REPUBLIQUE DEMOCRATIQUE DU CONGO
UNIVERSITE CATHOLIQUE DE BUKAVU
UCB
|
Willingness to pay of the notability for local leadership
empowerment in Ngweshe chiefdom
|
Research paper submitted in partial fulfillment for the
requirements of the graduate degree in Economics
|
By Roméo MUNGUAKONKWA Bahaya
|
Department of Rural Economics
|
Supervised by Professor Célestin BUCEKUDERHWA Bashige
Co-supervised by Assistant Jeanne-Nicole MUGOLI Menemene
|
Academic year: 2018-2019
EPIGRAPHY
«The last enemy that shall be destroyed is death»1
Cor. 15, 26.
IN MEMORIAM
To you,close sister Rebecca AKENGESA BAHAYA, your death
two weeks ago has left undesired the fulfillment of this work; may you find
herethe voice given to your feelings of participatingto its public
presentation.
With love and out of kindness to the moment we've shared
on earth, may your Soul rest in Peace!
Roméo MUNGUAKONKWA B.
DEDICATION
This paper is altogether dedicated to you, late sister
Rebecca AKENGESA Bahaya; you were till recently cherishing science before the
abrupt everlasting physicaldisappearence rose...
Roméo MUNGUAKONKWA B.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I acknowledge my almighty God for having tooled and
allowed me until the moment this work is done.
Thereafter, my thanks are addressed to the academic and
scientific professionals and the other workforce members of the
UniversitéCatholique de Bukavu who have born our circus until the
current acquired level.
To ProfessorCélestin BUCEKUDERHWA Bashige and
Assistant Jeanne-Nicole MUGOLI Menemenefor the demonstration of lots of care,
expertise and amandements brought to the entire research.
To my parents Valentin BAHAYA and Jeanette NZIGIRE; and
siblings - the BAHAYAs - for their love and support. This is one of proves of
your determination.
To my cousin and great friend Rodrigue BAHATI and family's
to whom I owe a big share of this achievement. Your self-denialis a shining
light to a bright and fantastic family's future youth.
To Uncles Jean BITEGESI and KAMUNGU Mushegerha and their
whole familieswhose support has remained indestructible.
To Cousin Jules FIREMBA,BrotherJeremie BASIMANE; Sister
Sylvie MUHIMUZIand their respective families for having been tied to my cause
and success. Your sacrifices are a big light to a bright and fantastic united
family.
To academic close friends Jonathan MUJINJI Bazibuhe and
Guillaume ZIRIMWABAGABO Mufinjwa who took start and end with me the academic
venture.
Much thanks as well to MrKapena Jean-Exaucé, the
Balezi's, the great family of apostles, the UCB English club members.
Thereafter to all academic fellows, social friends and
other persons omitted here; may you admit my greatest pleasure to acknowledge
all the forms of support provided during my hard but useful career.
Roméo MUNGUAKONKWA
B.
ACRONYMS
CRES: Consortium pour la Recherche Economique et
Sociale
CVM: Contingent Valuation Method
DFID: UK Department for International Development
DRC: Democratic Republic of the Congo
FAO: Food and Agriculture Organization
FCRN: Fonds Communautaire pour le Développement de
Ngweshe
ILO : International Labor Organization
JMDIMD: Joint Migration and Development Initiative
Migration for Development
LDC: Less Developed Countries
LIC: Lower Income Country
OECD: Organization for Economic Co-operation and
Development
UCB: Université Catholique de Bukavu
UNDP: United Nations Development Programme
US: United States
USD: United States Dollars
WTA: Willingness To Accept
WTP: Willingness To Pay
ABSTRACT
Pooling for local leadership empowerment in Ngweshe
chiefdomremains a useful action for local leadership survival. Local
development of the region appealed for different resources to thrive as many as
challenges have risen over the recent years. Accordingly, decentralization has
not covered the living conditions of the rural citizens living in the corner.
The current inverstigation assessed notables' WTP on the one hand and its
determinants on the other hand.Results indicate that notables have remained
strongly tied to their nativeland. It resorted to a snowball technique to
collect data on 180 native notables. With the use of Contingent valuation and
applying the interval regression method through Stata 14.0, the research has
revealed that the mean expressed WTP is $ 443.6262 to be yearly given. To this
is tied a caution to the chieftaincy to be transparent and accountable in
scheme accomplishment. Educational level, the number of persons of notoriety in
the notables' organization, notable monthly income, trust in local leaders,
assets index were found significant variables.
Key words: Willingness to pay,
Contingent valuation, Chiefdom, Local leadership, Notable, Development,
Ngweshe, Bukavu, DR Congo
RESUME
Contribuer pour la chefferie de Ngweshe est une action
importante pour la survie du leadership local. Le développement local de
la région a besoin de diverses ressources pour prospérer faces
aux multiples défis qui se sont levés au cours de récentes
années. A ce sujet, la décentralisation n'a pas couvert les
conditions de viedes populations rurales dans ledit coin.La présente
recherche a évalué d'une part le CAP des notables vivant à
Bukavu et d'autre part ses déterminants. Les résultats montrent
que les notables sont restés très attachés à leur
région natale. Elle a recouru à la technique de boule de neige
pour collecter les données sur 180 notables natifs de Ngweshe. En
utilisant l'évaluation contingente et en appliquant la régression
par intervalle à l'aide du logiciel Stata 14.0, la recherche
révèle que le Consentement à payer moyen exprimé
par les notables est de 443.6262 dollars américains par an. A ces
résultats sont liés une attention adressée aux chefs
locaux d'être transparents et redevables dans l'accomplissement des
projets. Les variables niveau d'éducation, le nombre de personnes de
notoriété dans l'association de notables, le revenu mensuel du
notable, la confiance dans le leadership local et l'indice des actifs se sont
révélées significatives.
Mots clés: Consentement
à payer, évaluation contingente, chefferie, leadership local,
notable, développement, Ngweshe, Bukavu, RD Congo.
INTRODUCTION
Notability has been quite a long time tied to local leadership
in seek of impeccable performance of local governance (Genieys et al., 2000).
Currently, local leadership is still internationally deemed as an irrefutable
means to promote development in remote and disadvantaged regions
(Rodriguez-Pose and Tijmstra, 2007; OECD, 2015;Uddin, 2019). Power transfer
from central to municipalities' elites is since reputed to nurture notable
locally engaged socioeconomic progress (OECD, 2015; Islam et al., 2019;Uddin,
2019).
Nevertheless, local leaders have been undermined by
considerable challenges to attain their target (Jha and Bhalla, 2018; Uddin,
2019). Mostly the situation is largely common to lower income countries (LIC's)
(Marysse, 2005; Gaynor, 2014). In fact, the most of these countries have
largely shown their incapacity to efficiently assure development in
municipalities (Romeo, 2013; Islam et al., 2019; Uddin, 2019). Some of them
maintain their control on municipalities, which in return sets back local
entities (Huque, 2014). Although lots of agreements have been internationally
signed regarding sustainable development, many governments are far from the
direct line leading to this target (Strange and Bayley, 2008). Despite
engagements and verbal determination from long date; their strategies to
strengthen local leadership usually fade to failure (Khan, 2012).
This problem is largely observable in numerous countries
worldwide. In Africa, in fact, the 1990s passed as decisively reformative
throughout decentralization (Erk, 2018). Local leaders in collaboration with
folks and their own attached notability were considered as hard hyphen elements
to boost local development (OECD, 2015; UNDP, 2015; Paarlberg and Yoshioka,
2016). This expectation was deemed successful regarding numerous monumental
work accomplished under several notables across other countries. For instance,
the development of movements of cooperatives in Germany or the construction of
the «Statue de Liberté» (Balemba and al., 2018). Such reforms
aimed at bettering democracy and policy performance through creating strong
local governments dealing with local folks (Chigwata, 2015). While a few
decades have faded, essays undertaken around the continent didn't work in many
countries (Romeo, 2013). According to him, rather than working as autonomous
localities, local governments are politized and remain under states leaders'
commend who immerse them into an extremist dependence. Such a contrast in legal
texts and empirical application of decentralization announces unproductive
issues of the policy (Romeo, 2013, Islam et al., 2019, Zongwe, 2019).
Predominantly in Sub-Saharan countries, local governments are
affected by the same scourge (Englebert and Kasongo, 2016). Applied
macroeconomic policies are no longer sufficient to lead to sustainable economic
growth (Swinburn and Yatta, 2006). A situation which indirectly diminishes
national effect at local leadership. Local leaders lack means to tackle their
politics and consequently bear their citizens' living standard improvement
(UN-HABITAT, 2010).
Democratic Republic of the Congo runs since the 1960's
governance challenges, bribery, insecurity, inequality distortion and a
widespread poverty (USIP, 2011; Maswana, 2018). To solve the matter, the
country believed in decentralization to bring a wholesome wave but, hell of it,
some worries have been noticed a few years after the 2006's democratic
elections denoting imperfections in legal applications of the retrocession
process (Englebert and Kasongo, 2016; Zongwe, 2019). Local leadership suffers
from weak institutions and political accountability mostly nourished at high
level of state decision makers (Gaynor, 2014).
Decentralization has been used as a means to collect funds
from bottom to central authorities followed by a provincial reduced management
capacity of revenues to be shared to substantial entities (BAD and FAD 2009;
Englebert and Kasongo, 2016). Recently, provincial governors nationwide began
claiming at the Congolese Central Government to pay back their arrears whereas
local leaders in the Territorial Decentralized Entities have eyes turned at
national reallocation for their empowerment but without success.1(*) Since donors jeopardize
decentralization fulfillment (Martinez-Vazquez and Vaillancourt, 2011), in
default of consistent means, local governments fail to introduce policies and
schemes sensitive to provoke local economic raise (Masango, 2002; Zongwe, 2019)
in a context of an impoverished nation wanting a prompt development (UNDP,
2013).
Local leadership empowerment, as a key factor of development,
has interested several researchers worldwide. Local government is an important
center of service delivery as it is closer to the people (OECD, 2015; Islam et
al., 2019; Uddin, 2019). A local leader at the present time plays various roles
than in the past (UNDP, 2015; Wall and Luther, 2015). As well, Nahavandi (2000)
insists on the fact that a leader's efficiency depends on his group's level of
performance. Local development should hence be supported by all local forces
like local folks, notability, religious authorities through human capital
empowerment for productivity enhancement (UNDP, 2015). Moreover, a proficient
local leader owes to assure residents' satisfaction and is required to be
preparedness for all subsequent disasters that in all likelihood may affect
them (Hall et al., 2015; OECD, 2015; Targa-AIDE and Collectif et
Modernité, 2015). People should then objectively grant their local
leadership to initiate various projects at the bottom. For instance, the World
Bank has noticed a rising in local levy collection in Ibanda Commune and Kabare
chiefdom from 7% to 12%2(*),
a success that led up to beginning generalizing of the process
nationwide.3(*)
Besides, there exists a flurry of work carried on local
developmental leadership but very little match with notability. Republic of
South Africa (1998), UN-HABITAT (2010), Myerson (2011), Nkwana (2012), OECD
(2015), Huque (2014), Wall and Luther (2015), Targa-AIDE and Collectif et
Modernité (2015). Myerson (2011), Nkwana (2012), Targa-AIDE and
CollectifetModernité (2015) extol a net transfer of a few assignments of
competence from central to local leaders. Huque (2014) highlights the absence
of appropriated strategies and facilities for local leaders development in
Bangladesh due to the state leaders oversees and lets a shadow on meaningful
policies to putdown the challenge. Such OECD (2015) states four local
leadership features: they are ambitious and give a new positive hope mostly
after crisis, they vision the future to define a new development path and
significant strategies to face dynamics, put down coordination failures and
lastly recognize that they make positive progress in terms of valuable economic
and employment opportunities. Accordingly, Carmen and Kristina (2009),
Nkwana(2012), OECD (2015), local leaders should be accountable and transparent
with people they lead for more faith renewability.
Also, Schlachter et al. (2013) finds some key challenges of
local development directly or indirectly related to fiscal crisis in
Pennsylvania, of which managing the budgetary demands of decreased revenues,
increased service demands and the costs of unfunded state and federal mandates,
and meeting the demands of infrastructure and its associated costs. In fact,
Zhang (1996) and Lai (2010) explain how the Chinese Deng Xiaoping's 1979
reforms decentralized the economic pole and resulted in a popular participation
and consecutively an impressive growth in the 1980s-1990s that undeniably set
non-negotiable foundation of the current Chinese economic openings. Rather than
seeing the community like a national policy abider, Carmen and Kristina (2009),
Wall and Luther (2015) and OECD (2015) confirm the horizontal relationship
between local leaders and residents with different role to play throughout
positive insights to development. A local leader is hence undermined by central
and communal requirement he should successfully link and fully respond to local
developmental challenges (Wall and Luther, 2015; Islam et al., 2019).
But Crook (2003) whose research concerned Africa matches local
leader's capacity to mitigate poverty with the degree of local-state leader's
relationship. He concluded his research stating that decentralization did not
empower challenges to local leaders in Africa because they remained indifferent
or against pro-poor policies. For Trautman (2013), the key factors of state
failure in DRC are outdated state infrastructure, lack of economic
development, and external intervention . Marysse (2005) has asseverated that
the motivational text related to the proposal of law on decentralization in DRC
aims at realizingequilibrium between attributions and
means in the decentralized units. Notwithstanding, and exactly,
Martinez-Vazquez and Vaillancourt (2011) support the obstacle of
decentralization reforms to have political and economic origins. In contrast
with such research issues, UN-HABITAT (2010) finds that applied municipal
policies in Gaborone diminished the rate of street beggars and street boys.
UNDP (2013) as well shows positive results in local-based infrastructures
within the Congolese Territorial Decentralized Entities. Not so far, Peemans
(2015) support the existence of a huge potentiality of a «peasantry mode
of development» in DR Congo whose effect shall rely on initiatives and
fights of an organized peasantry world.
Though prior papers such as DFID (2008), Targa-AIDE and
Collectif et Modernité (2015) have suggested a local leadership
promotion assured by government or/ and NGOs on the one hand and UNDP (2015)
Englebert and Kasongo (2016) and Uddin (2019) suggesting to empower folks under
local government institutions on the other hand, this work supports local
leadership partly born by native notables in search of development. Notables
dwelling in Bukavu would help to finance local-based investment needed for
their provenance countryside's development. Accounting for this issue requires
mainly assessing Willingness to pay of the notability towards local leadership
empowerment in the Chiefdom of Ngweshe. Also, the research specifically aims at
denoting what are the determinants of their willingness to pay. Local
leadership will here refer to local Chieftaincy, chiefs of groupings whereas
notability will concern individuals with higher notoriety, or the nature of
wealth. As well, confidence renewal resulting from this common acting-line is
likely to accelerate the process with worth of positive economic outcomes.
The Contingent valuation method (CVM) shall be applied in data
collection on the notability of Bukavu town issued from the Chiefdom of
Ngweshe. An ample literature has recommended the use of The CVM since it aims
at clarify the amount to be pooled in a policy-maker's perspective Hanemann
(1989); Carson (2000); Duberstein and Steiguer (2003); Dror, Radermacher and
Koren (2006); Vassilis and Kostas (2010).An interval regression shall help to
assess the determinants of WTP and the amount consented as did Corso et al.
(2013) and Labii (2015). Given the method, this paper will capture for how much
major individuals will to pay to reinforce local leadership in their entity.
The paper dwells on three chapters after an introducing part
and passes off with a conclusion. The literature review as first chapter is
devoted to exposing an overview of the availed flow of knowledge on the matter
whose study is the ineluctable goal of this paper. The second chapter concerns
the research methodology. It gives exhaustive elicitations on how the research
has evolved with tools and methods used for the purpose. At last, the third is
the study and interpretation of findings that provides a response to our
concern and works out the present research.
Chapter one: LITERATURE REVIEW
This chapter brings to light the available precognition flows
on the research issue. It is subdivided into three main sections: the
conceptual framework, theories and hypotheses building on variables.
I. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK
The conceptual framework as the first section is about to
define and explicit the research concepts setting this topic.
I.1. Local leadership
empowerment
What leadership is? How did it rise across eras? What should
be understood as local leadership empowerment?The present subsection comes to
answer these questions.
The concept of leadership
Brief history of leadership
Leadership is as old as societies have been made up. An
important wave of changes till the current consideration has been noticed over
eras. Therefore, during the antiquity, leadership was attributed to either
divine or mythic source. A huge establishment of kingdoms and empires has
followed and was set on the same ideology. For instance, the Roman Kingdom, the
Trojan kingdom, the Greece empire, Carthage, etc. At these times, leaders
passed to be authoritarian, insulated from others, liked overdone obedience,
and misused fear and abuse to pressure folks. As a result, people were
persuaded that only a few individuals were able to lead. In contrast, in the
course of Middle Age, power has been continuously transferred from kings to
parliaments. Thus, there intervenesa question of source of power. Rousseau
(1762) in his «Social Contract» insisted on the population as source
of authority. The lift-off of democracy made elected leaders to be accountable
vis-à-vis to people they represented. However, it has been noticed that
most of time they were not accountable and that they were misusing their
authority than people could want. In the contemporary times, yet democratic
process is applied to design the leader but people no longer understand that
being accountable depend on one leader's will. Reason why, all over the world,
some nations adopted democracy, while others are under despotism. Currently,
leadership has taken an institutional and organizational trend viewed as a
combination of inborn and achieved qualities.
What the concept is about
Many authors have attempted to define, with some differences,
the concept leadership. Some particularly selected are UNDP (2006), Smith
(2010), Ganta and Manukonda (2014) and Madanchian et al. (2017).
In fact, Smith (2010) considers leadership as the ability to
adapt the setting so everyone feels empowered to contribute creatively to solve
the problems.
Madanchian et al. (2017) likewise deems that «the
effective leader creates the situation that is best for the organization
through the use of skills and process.»
The most global consideration of leadership comes from UNDP
(2006) for which the vision of leadership is to focus on the relationship of
individuals to the group, concentrating on the development of the collective
rather than on a single role in the whole. So, leadership depends on both power
- the ability to influence people - and authority - the ability to
influence decisions-making and resource allocation. (UNDP, 2006).
The definition brings out that a leader should demonstrate
meaningful qualities helping him to perceive or expect a problem, to define
effective strategies to resolve it. Therefore, a collective action is needed
from collective hands without which a leader will struggle into inefficiency
and failure.
In the same boat, Ganta and Manikonda (2014) consider as
leadership, «a kind of power where one person has the ability to influence
or change the values, the beliefs, behavior and attitudes of another
person». Though their definitions are not altogether different, important
precisions are pinned on. In its core, it proposes a profound alteration in
one's inner. Another consignment is advanced by Huque (2014) for whom local
leadership in underdeveloped countries is related to traditional and cultural
aspects of power and authority, and their application on how leading
localities. In that event, four categories of local leadership were given by
Khan (1999) including elder or senior village headmen, dispute settlers,
village politicians, and people acknowledged as men of honor.
In this study, a «local leader» refers to a
traditionally-established and traditionally-tied (elected or designed)
authority whose purpose is to lead and defend folks' interests in general. They
are here considered to be established in countryside rather than in town, to
lead rural folks rather than urban and maintain their control in their entities
rather than nearby town. This definition is inspired from attributions and
duties of rural chieftaincy toward their folks around the chiefdom.
Local leadership empwowerment is
thus approached as an act by which an individual undertakes to strengthen local
leadership in order to archieve it objectives through one or more mechanisms,
such as monetary donation, assets, capacity building, etc. This study preaches
contributions of notables dwelling in bukavu to ermpower local leaders only
taking into account monetary donation. This is consecutive to the insignificant
amount allowed to these authorities in terms of retrocession to boost local
development in their entity. Though there is no legal obligation to do so,
moral and social obligations can be tied to that practive already lauched in
gain of the chiefdom.
I.2.
Notable
«Notable» is an old concept whose sence has changed
depending to the variability of governance and eras. A very broad and recent
consideration of the concept «notable» recognizes notables, within
social groups, as personnalities of a supposedly important rank, destined to
have particular ascendancy and a dominating influence on the other members of
the society. The concept of Notable is therefore inseparable from that of
social hierarchy; sometimes they can be personnalities to which the population
spontaneously recognizes a particular importance which distinguishes them from
others.4(*)People are
notable owing to public responsibility, accomplishment or, even mere
participations in the celebrity industry.» (The Leverson enquiry,
2012).
The concept appeared in the history in Gaules (France) in the
post evolution as leaders of municipalities.Hence appeared a class of local
regime replacing the notability and bourgeoisie. Charles (1997) support that in
the area, a notable was defined considering the nature of their social;
economic and political resources that he held within the configuration of a
particular political regime. But during the independence, for instance Morocco,
but alsoin the former running colonization, public authorities have
consolidated one category of leader in particular: the traditional notable; a
designation based on ethnic and lineage affiliation in political mobilization
(Tozy, 2009). The traditional notable asserted his legitimacy on his direct
relationship with agents of the state, on a large land property (obtained by
inheritance and/or because one of the redistribution of the lands of the
colonists by the independent state) and on other resources distributed by the
state such as grants.
I.3. Chieftaincy
According to Bob-Milliar (2009), chieftaincy is defined as
«an indigenous system of governance with executive, juridical and
legislative powers». There are various forms of traditional rulership
found in Africa prior to colonialism (Boakye and Béland, 2018). The
literature pins various kinds of rulership through different district styles
described as chieftaincy (Boakye and Béland, 2018). However, the kind
of power they exercises remains totally different.
The term chieftaincy or chief was a creation of colonial
administrators (Bob-Milliar, 2009) who allowed definable titles to the
traditional leaders they met - chiefs and warrant - for the purpose of making
categories within their administrative structure (Boakye and Béland,
2018).
II.THEORIES
After the above-mentioned overview of the research concepts,
this other share gives an overview on the way that local governance is legally
set in the Democratic Republic of the Congo. It first provides a laconic
material on what is to be considered as local governance through which local
leaders emerge and how they are legally supported either politically or
economically. The purpose of both trends' combination is attempting to develop
local entities. The following sub-section as for it provides several ways to
reinforce local governance throughout the available literature.
II.1. Local government in
Democratic Republic of the Congo
III.1.1. Governance organization
In DR Congo, the form of governance has been seen as a result
of a great wave of confrontation between a unitary-ruled state and federalism
supporters. This controversy led to the creation of new provinces and within
them decentralization was established (BAD and FAD, 2009; Englebert and
Kasongo, 2016). The article 2 and 3 of the constitution and article 3-5 of the
organic law no. 08/016 of 7 October 2008 relative to the composition;
organization and functioning of the decentralized territorial entities and
their relations with the state and provinces distinguish three kinds of
territorial entities. They are provinces, Decentralized Territorial Entities
(EntitésTerritorialesDécentralisés) and
Deconcentrated Territorial Entities
(EntitésTerritorialesDéconcentrées).This
legislation breaks with the past by the fact that it directly preaches
decentralization for which the golden rule is to consolidate national unity,
eroded by successive wars, and to create impetus and development centers at the
grassroots (Zongwe, 2019). Are considered as Deconcentrated Territorial
Entities: territories, quarters, groupings and village. On the other hand,
cities, communes, sectors and chiefdoms compose the category of Decentralized
Territorial Entities. At the local level, the head of the executive is the
mayor (maire), burgomaster (bourgmestre), head of sector
(chef de secteur), and head of chiefdom (chef de chefferie),
in accordance with the territorial entity under which they exercise their
authority: cities, communes, sectors and chiefdoms, respectively (Zongwe,
2019).
Specifically, the Congolese law defines the chiefdom
(chefferie) as a group of homogenous traditional communities organized
and led in reference to customary laws (Zongwe, 2019). Among the other
Decentralized Territorial Entities and Deconcentrated Territorial Entities; it
is the only one to which a legal personality is recognized. In such a
situation, the Congolese central government recognizes and vests the leader of
chiefdoms. He is appointed in terms of the applicable customary law.
III.1.2. Legal financial disposal for local governance
and failure of decentralization
The Congolese law requires a net autonomy and separation of
each local entity's budget from the others'. The constitution of the DR Congo
defines in its article 203, as modified by the law n° 11/002 of January
20, 2011, the establishment of taxes including exercise and consumer taxes. It
requires, however, the avoidance of tax duplication between provinces and the
central government. Furthermore, the revenue-sharing formula and financial
transfers from central toward the province should legally translate 50% of
national tax revenue, transfers of 40% of the national tax revenue directly to
provinces and 10% to the National Equalization Fund (Caisse National de
Perequation) and the remaining 50% are kept at national level (BAD and
FAD, 2009).
But as deem Englebert and Kasongo (2016) and Zongwe (2019),
the budgets of provinces and other entities remain meager to tackle their
policy and strengthen their faith towards the folks they lead. As a result, the
mission of decentralization has not come closer to its fulfillment. Only a
slice of the reforms that the Congolese nation has waited for has been
undertaken. This is mainly due to a much narrowed share of the budget allowed
to decentralization on one side, and an unfulfilled application and
disbursement of the amount towards political entities (Englebert and Kasongo,
2016).
Table one: Status Decentralization Reforms in the DRC
in June 2015
Reform
|
Status
|
Self-administration of provinces and ETDs
|
Law passed (`8), poorly implemented*
|
Conference of governors
|
Law passed (`8), poorly implemented
|
Provincial elections
|
One (`7); not since
|
Financial transfers (`retrocession')
|
Partial
|
New Public Finance law
|
Law passed (`11)
|
Public investment fund for provinces**
|
No
|
Creation of new provinces (`decoupage')
|
Law promulgated March 15***
|
ETD Elections
|
No
|
Transfer of jurisdiction in decentralized areas
|
No
|
Transfer of personnel to provincial ministries
|
No
|
Separating decentralized and deconcentrated services
|
No
|
Reform of public service
|
No
|
Transfer of assets `patrimoine' to provinces
|
No
|
Transparency of provincial expenditure chains
|
No****
|
Source: Englebert and Kasongo
(2016)
*Undermined by 2011 constitutional reform which authorizes
the president to move provincial governors and appoint new ones.
** National Equalization Fund
***Undermined by subsequent appointment of «special
commissioners» by the president, and suspension of provincial assemblies.
****Aside from ex post audits by «cour des
comptes» in 2013 for the 2011 accounts of seven provinces5(*)
Near from this fact, three provinces (Katanga, Kinshasa and
Kongo Central) receive about 90% of total amounts of retrocession whereas
others remain very far behind. In 2013, for instance, Katanga received U.S.USD
300 million, and respectively 54 and 21 million allocated to Kinshasa and Kongo
Central.
II.2. Empowering local
leadership
II.2.1. Empowerment through skills building
The experience of public participation in local governments
has not yet effectively matched with the legislations and community expectation
(Panday, 2019). The structure of power distribution in local government, the
level of maturity of political parties and institutions, and other unnumbered
factors can be a veritable setback to leaders' designation. Other factors like
social structure, low level of literacy, social mobility and demand of national
development in the country deepens chaotic effects on local leadership (Huque,
2014). He further emphasizes that political instability in local entities
produces significant shakes in the economic thrive lowering developmental
actions initiated to put down obstacles to local development (Huque, 2014).A
bidirectional hold can mostly result from the source of income used up local
leaders. As known, it is evident that all administrations need means to realize
their goals (OECD, 2015). Sources vary from a leader to another. Most of times,
in a well-bordered region, all local leaders do not access identically to
resources (Englebert and Kasongo, 2016). Such differences create in a country
two categories of local leaders. Those yet empowered by their entity's
resources relatively abide for national orders preventing them from shattering
their citizens' interest, others with meaningless resources bow and serve
national leaders especially in Less Developed Countries (Englebert and Kasongo,
2016). Thus, leaders can easily abandon their assigned mission of serving the
population. When arrangements aiming at preparing leaders for local government
altogether fail, in developing countries mainly, informal sectors are locally
used to fund local leadership running. While local leadership remains strongly
needed in the true process of development, a few worries remain on their
capacity to exactly set policies and objectively use funds in interest of their
population (Caldeira et al., 2012).
Fiszbein (1997) and Huque (2014) visibly exploit that
challenge respectively in Columbia and Bangladesh. Of course, local leaders
should be well formed because all undertaken actions in their function results
in success or failure of their folks. Leadership development attempts to
involve the participation and commitment of the current and potential leaders,
provide them with a process of skills building connect them to additional
information and resources to open them to big progress in their community.
The role played by responsible and innovative policies in
strengthening the capacity of local governments is quite complex. First, a
local leader is well placed to prompt local administration under his control to
improve its performance and, as a result, generate demand for
capacity-enhancing activities. Second, they should be a key element to provide
local capacity (Fiszbein, 1997). Local administration should also exploit the
internal underused strength in the process; the existence of latent unused
force in the administration. In a nutshell, important arsenal of wisdom and
know-how is requisite for a dynamic and liberal local leader.
II.2.2. Empowerment through communal participation
Involvement of the community through formal or informal
channels like voicing demand, making choice or being involved in project done
either by an individual or a community is another form to enhance sustainable
local leadership (Fiszbein, 1997). According to Sopchokchai (1996), one
approach in creating sustainable rural development is through giving to the
community an opportunity to plan and think their own future. As residents get
to stand as contributors and monitors, notable progress can raise and the level
of leaders' accountability can also thrive with such participation. But the
extent to which community participation is transformed and results into
capacity enhancement depends on inclination and to a certain extent boldness of
local administration (Fiszbein, 1997). The experience of Colombian reforms in
the fading nineteenth focused on facilitating the participation of citizens
through an opening of their nearby administration. Without any shadow of doubt,
the approach to public policy has succeeded in Villedupar. What is a good and
practical example of collaboration of local leadership and the community, and
extensively of notability. As realized in Villadupar, advances Fiszbein (1997),
community participation became the tenor and base of villadupar's development
while in municipal offices leaders motive them through a remarkable sentence
«we govern with your participation». As it is noticed in the
work of Ozor and Nwankwo (2008), the true success of a comprehensive economic
and social development programs in the context of Nigeria is primarily
dependent to the extent it improves the well-being of rural human beings.
Additionally, there is no sustainable community development under force and
order. But rather than being petrifying the community, it is like to be
achieved when all actors are ready participating and share constructive ideas,
visions, responsibilities equally and democratically in implementing communal
or village development schemes (Ajayi and Otuya, 2006).
II.2.2.1 The place of WTP in decision and
achievement
It is notwithstanding conventional to use compensation and
equivalent variations when capturing the effect of price changes on welfare.
Both measures respectively correspond to the maximum amount an individual would
be willing to pay (WTP) and the minimum amount somebody would be willing to
accept (WTA) to forgo it (Hanneman, 1989).
Principally arisen to measure the value of public goods and
services, the concept WTP remains currently used in contingent valuation
concerns. That is, attribution of non-market goods or resources.6(*) Three streams have stuck on the
contingent valuation method. The first, which is dominant in the literature,
uses contingent valuation in experiments in the field of environment.
Respondents were asked to express the maximum amount they would like to give.
The second took another form of bidding games whereas the third principally
mattered of statistical model of data process (Alberini and Kahn, 2006; Labii,
2015). The guidance is indeed the utility provided by the good to be acquired
by means after disbursement. The following subsection shows the principals on
which is set this relationship between utility and WTP.
II.2.2.2. Willingness to pay as a result of one's
preference
The notion of willingness to pay broadly roots from consumer's
demand function (Varian, 1992). Opting for paying can be beheld as the
translation of one's utility got from a related good or service (Varian, 1992;
Jha and Bhalla, 2018). But being unwilling to pay for a commodity should not
intuitively pass as an evidence of total absence of willingness to pay (Matraia
et al., 2006). It all depends on the opportunity cost that forgoing a slight
share of one's income implies (Jha and Bhalla, 2018).
Jha and Bhalla (2018) hereon highlight willingness to engage
and the ability to engage referring to community aptitude to contribute for
contending poverty. Associated engagement thus relies on sensitization of new
community members to lift the impact of their action toward the target.
Let's then consider a collection of consumers as referred to
Varian (1992). Each one of them faces a demand function for some k commodities
so that a consumer's demand function becomes a vector for .
Note: goods are indicated by superscripts while consumers are
indicated by subscripts.
Aggregating these individual demands helps to obtain a unique
aggregate demand function
defined by .Then, the aggregate demand for goods can be denoted by ; with m, the vector of incomes ). As a centralizing function, the aggregate function is made of
individual demand function characteristics. A reference is for instance
directly taken from continuity of the individual demand function. Assume a
consumer is able to acquire only one chair for given price . At any other price such as exceeds the initial price , consumer demands zero of the good. On the other hand, each other price inferior or equal to implies 's consumption of one unit of the good. From this demonstration,
consumer's preference can be ranked by the means of this set of prices: such as [ ] represents consumer willingness to pay side and, in contrast, at the consumer can't face the proposed price higher than the initial
price and, as result, none is disposed to pay.
Indeed, WTP of public goods such as environment conservation
or getting comfortable infrastructure is relatively complex. In light of this,
better is to understand how WTP varies regarding to the transparency of
institutions.
II.2.2.3. Institutional trust and Willingness to pay
When people are needed to pool for a common good or service,
what first happens for each one of them is somehow hedonic. Gain motives first
their decisions towards disbursing for a given realization. Multiple are those
kinds of communal schemes that have failed and so are state-folks cooperation
in specific developmental ventures when one of the part is not seriously
engaged in the ideology and practical fulfillment.
From that mood, willingness to pay is affected by the
institutional trust (Macias and Williams, 2014). Jin (2013) defines
institutional trust as «the extent to which citizens have confidence in
public institutions to operate in the best interest of society and its
constituents». The credibility and legitimacy of developmental policies
reflect a successful fulfillment of people's trust in institutions (Islam et
al., 2019; Uddin, 2019). "The lower the level of trust in the state actors
tasked with the provision of the public good, the lower the likely valuation
individuals will attach to the good in question which ultimately affects their
WTP toward its provision" (Marbuah, 2016). Other needful elements in bettering
community-governance interaction are transparency and accountability of the
ruling regime. Both elements must be conveyed through access to information
(Ampa, 2018). The issue of mistrust in institutions has been found to be one of
the main reasons for citizens' protest responses and lower WTP in many
environmental valuation studies (Jones et al., 2008; Polyzouet al., 2011).
II.2.3. The place of diaspora in local development
Diasporas have got increasingly various roles to play in rural
development (JMDIMD, 2011). Flows of migrant transfers are becoming
increasingly important comparatively to other regions in some countries. In
Senegal for instance, the World Bank and CRES (2009) have noticed the highest
share of transfers from the diaspora in direction of rural areas. They also
noticed that many of the migrant were issued from countrysides in search of
good living conditions. This would have led to expecting important
rapprochements between development practitioners on one side and policy makers
on the other side. Since, governments carry on policies and measures that are
favorable to flourishing important activities. (OIM and MPI, 2012;
Africa-Europe Platform, 2014). Doing so, governments set lucid conditions
allowing diaspora to directly send financial means as easily as possible to
home residents in their country. Diasporas are therefore like a core potential
for lighting several ways to intervene in assuring the current and future
development process (Africa-Europe Platform, 2014; Nishikant and Priyanka,
2018). This is mainly because they originally issued from their peasant
community with whom they share the same culture, language, local insights and
emotional ties. Cohen (1980) in Brinkerhoff (2008) identifies a range of
features common to Diasporas including:
· A collective memory and myth about the homeland
· An idealization of the putative ancestral home and a
collective commitment to its maintenance, restoration, safety and prosperity,
even to its creation.
· The development of a return movement which gains
collective approbation.
· A strong ethnic group consciousness sustained over a
long time and based on a sense of distinctiveness, a common history and the
belief in a common fate, and
· A sense of empathy and solidarity with co-ethnic
members in other countries of settlement.
All these features are requisite in fighting against poverty
with regard to development of communities' identity, where members boost their
tie to home culture and subsequent values. Diaspora then becomes consequently
empowered to community livelihood changes, additional information and
communication technology facilitating them to remain tied to their homeland
community (Africa-Europe Platform, 2014).
In Europe, there are currently a lot of African diaspora
organizations and groups with high philanthropic purpose for rural and
community development in the homeland countries (Africa-Europe Platform, 2014).
Most of them are located in North-western Europe while others are spread in
other European countries like France, UK, Germany, etc. Organizations located
in France were found to actively intervene in Africa. The main share of
transfers is allowed to West African and Maghreb countries. Meaningful diaspora
remittances are recorded from East Africa related to Somalia, Ethiopia and
Kenya; and Zimbabwe, Angola and the Republic of South Africa from the South
African region. Diaspora groups from the Democratic Republic of the Congo and
Cameroon in Central Africa and from Cape Verde are also actively involved in
rural and community development in their country of origin (Africa-Europe
Platform, 2014).
Globally, these characteristics of remittances discussed above
show that transfers, often characterized by stability and absence of
cyclicality, could have a significant impact in bringing to light the economic
pressure on receivers while, based on the criterion of sustainability,
financial flows diminish over time owing to the fading of the migrant's
motivation. This paper examines the WTP of internal notables that have migrated
from their chiefdom for dwelling in Bukavu town in the nick of time of
development.
III. HYPOTHESES BUILDING ON THE
RESEARCH TOPIC
Scholars on willingness to pay are numerous. Although these
step aside in several fields, they usually have in common certain variables.
Age of the respondent, educational level, notable's income, etc. are variable
empirically used to assess one's willingness to pay (Miwoto et al., 2017). In
this research, a lot of variables are retained such as age of the notable,
years of schooling, index of assets, amount of educational burden, starting
price in the referendum, grouping selected for scheme, Household size, income,
etc. These variables are ranged over one regression function as independent
variables with Willingness to pay as dependent variable. Thus, to illustrate
the model, a built theoretical design is in opposite given:
Age
Important project in the grouping
Household size
Set priceamount
NumOrgangro
Trustin local leaders
Notable'smonthlyincome
Educational level
Membership of an organization
Duration in town
WTP
Figu1re 1.Theoretical model
Index ofassets
Source: Own conception based on the research literature
As abovementioned, analyses are carried on what determines
notables WTP through scheme of leadership empowerment. That is, to reinforce
and support local leaders to realize developmental project in Ngweshe.
As already said, eleven variables are used here to assess the
power determinors of Willingness to pay. Hypothesis built on them consider H0
when results don't confirm the expected
H1. Age influence on Willingness to
pay
The link between age and WTP remains unpredictable. In fact,
studies like Cortina et al; (2014) and ILO (2019) deem that migration opens
young women and men to opportunities for obtaining productive and comfortable
jobs, improve their socio-economic status, learn new skills, and raise their
physical and human capital. The statement means in other words that young are
more likely to realize higher income. Explaining this statement also refers to
a prior work of Gimba and Kumshe (2011) who found that 77% of rural-urban
migrants were less than 40 years. Mowito et al. (2017) later show that more
an individual is older more he is conscious with advantages of forest
conservation and consequently can provide much for his native region. Dror,
Radermacher and Koren et al (2006) for instance found age being significantly
positively associated with WTP. Fonta et al. (2011) as well assessed in
Bambalang community of Ngoketunjia Division, North West Province, in Cameroon
confirms the result; these researchers used a logarithm of age to test which
link would result from a contingent valuation analysis predicate
community-based project they found a positive link between age and acceptance.
H2. Household size and notable's willingness to
pay
An expectation sustained by Kuepie (2018) show that household
size, as a translation of fertility, drops the well-being of members through
all per capita consumptions (food, human capital, housing and durable goods) in
Madagascar. Announced as a burden, it may prevent the notability from
disbursing some amount to home leaders. Very earlier, Arthur (2005) shows that
family size is an important instrument of trading-off whether a family or an
individual is poor. When they are already married or have other individuals to
directly support in the urban area, at a set level of income, rural migrants'
willingness to pay for rural development drops in response to some alteration
implied by additional burden. Deficiency in the provenance countryside can be
since observed through shortage in investment and household's consumption, a
setback to rural development (Saika, 2010; FAO, 2018).
H3. Level of education and Willingness to
pay
Taking a side in the link between level of education with
participation would be equivocal. In fact, two contrasting voices
have risen from the literature deeming simultaneously positive and negative
relationship. When individuals leave the countryside migrating to town, among
them are schooled and non-schooled individuals. Besides the movement, migrants
with high education level incorporate qualities and knowledge that is used to
raise urban productivity rather than allowing rural production and food
auto-sufficiency. According to Gimba and Kumshe (2011), when instructed
individuals leave the countryside they town the town productive though counts
against rural thrive. What visibly undermines rural development and implies
countryside of origin struggle under, continuous poverty. In contrast, Fonta et
al. (2011), Borjas (2016) and Mowito et al. (2017) asseverate that numerous
years at school permits to acquire knowledge and, relatively, consenting to be
an actor in a leadership improvement project is higher as greater are the
number of years spent at school. The variable level of education was found
significant at 99% by Mowito et al. (2017). As for Ajayi (2006), the mean years
of formal education was 13,55 years with a standard deviation of 7,10 and
86,41% of surveyed sample could read and write.
H.4. Duration in Town and WTP for local leadership
empowerment
Philanthropy is a way to abandon one's ownership to others
without any compensation. Thus, they usually diminish over time. Salomone
(2006), for example, calls sustainability of remittances, the link existing
between the duration spent by a migrant in the destination country. According
to Saika (2010), the literature on sustainability establishes on a negative
relationship between remittances and the duration of the migrant in the host
country. He thus argues that it is evident after five years on the host land.
The international Migration Organization deems the same changes when a migrant
has got in the intention to remit and the duration spent abroad. The phenomenon
happens when the legal status changes or when they are opened labor contract
hired (Salomone, 2006). This study is set on the same pillars: it adopts a
hypothesis (H=1) to mean a negative link and (H=0) otherwise.
H.5. Membership of the organization ameliorate
WTP
An organization is a structure of individuals who work
together to achieve that same goals. Uddin (2019) is favorable to the idea. He
supports that being share of an acting group is determinant for somebody to
participate. Joining a social community group to participate to local
government translated in Union Parishad (Bangladesh) a double effect: first, as
an opportunity to be a witness of the movement in local institutions but also
important and second as an apparatus of empowerment. World Bank and CRES
(2009), Saika (2010) underline the existence of groups of migrants from
Bangladesh who try some initiatives to realize their investments in the native
land. They have even taken through meetings of brainstorming they regularly
realize an initiative aiming at influencing the US government to invest in
Bangladesh. It is admissible to think of the gathering of notables as a
positive insight to adding on WTP. Each member would present in this
research a non-void added value to share and fructify the goal achievement.
H6. Income profoundly and willingness to pay
Income is expected to positivelyinfluence the amount sent to
local leaders. In fact, either do neoclassic or Keynesian theories profess a
positive link between income and the purchasing power of an economic agent. An
empirical investigation under Miwoto et al. (2017) shows for instance that the
expected income from activities realized in the forest has a positive and
significant influence on the willingness to pay of households. Casey et al.
(2006) and Bliki (2011) also asseverate a positive link between income and WTP.
Haddak et al (2014) applied both Logit and Tobit models on the population of
Rhône which was divided into two groups and their findings were that the
more household income is high, furthermore the contribution is important and
more a challenge is likely solvable.
H7. Trust in local leadership and WTP towards
local leadership development
The job of backing up population's wellbeing starts locally in
people neighborhood and communities (OECD, 2015; Public Health England, 2015).
What is exactly common worldwide to communities is further having in head a
leader to channel people's performance. Weakness of leadership trust translated
by disagreement between the local leaders and grassroots was empirically raised
by Ozor and Nwankwo (2008) as a major constraint to both partners to go
together over local development in Nigeria. As the same empirical research
denotes, a major constraint tied to the preceding is without doubt the lack of
appropriate mechanisms for disciplining erring local leaders. On the other
hand, it emerged that the lack of interest in community development programmes
was not a constraint. Over social inefficiency, local development, leadership
efficiency and leader-folks partnership are in crisis. The same situation was
confirmed in Bangladesh by Saika (2010) who highlighted that people living in
host county (USA) worry with the development of their country but retain their
attention on local capacity to exactly fulfill investments they may pool for.
Thus, over times asking to people to put a share of their revenues to boost
leadership might look like equivocal. They might be discouraged by the
way local leaders are mismanaging their destiny. Furthermore at national level,
most countries have renewed their collection system from natives living abroad
by the culture of transparency and reasonable investments (Saika, 2010).
H.8. Belonging to various organizations and WTP
Although the literature is insignificant on this variable
regarding the exact and optimal tool of organization to which an individual
should belong so as his WTP grows, the research hypothesis is altogether
different from the preceding (see H.5). While it is scientifically
deemed that participation into a group or social organization is a useful trump
to address meaningful actions, belonging to many organization for a notable may
run his Willingness To pay. The argument is based on what exactly sets the
goals and rules the organization. As they differently function, the same member
is wanted in each one of the organizations to contribute. Consequently, the
same amount that could be cashed in the notables' organization account is
divided into shares as if he was making a portfolio.
H.9. Index of assets and WTP
Index of assets may count for WTP for empowering local
leadership. Asset Index reflects the economic wealth which involves a feature
of being divided (Feumou, 2002). It summarizes how can assets reflect whether
one is poor or well-off. Feunou (2002) shows the existence of a huge link
between the number of assets owned by an individual and wealth. He pursues
illustrating with the Zambian evidence. In fact, his findings deem that owning
assets in Zambia grows at average accordingly to wealth. Labii (2015) realized
that citizen of Bukavu who access to electricity are relatively well-off
possess a greater number of assets than others. The same area constituted our
research field and try to consider how important were notables' assets in terms
of number and value.
H10. Set price influences and willingness to
pay
Setting price would tend to reduce one's willingness to pay.
In fact, voluntary and mainly altruistic decisions are often thoroughly
operated, for rational individuals, with all attention to remain capable to
grapple with ulterior challenges (Saika, 2010). As a result, Fonta et al.
(2011) found that as higher as the set price will enhance the contributors'
number to thrust toward fall. This variable reflects a cost of a communal good
it means «empowered leadership», although economically cost is to be
minimized. Varian (1992) denotes an adverse link between price and demand of
collective goods.
H11. Grouping selected for an important scheme and
willingness to pay
Grouping selected for an important scheme likely motives
notables to remit for local leadership empowerment.
In fact, notables, like all other citizens worldwide, are
strongly tied to their native regions and communities. Individuals seem to feel
more tied to native groupings rather than any other grouping of their chiefdom.
What indeed translated their citizenship. In the literature, migrant, for
instance, are shown to remain strongly tied to their homelands with concrete
realization like remittance to their community (Sheffer, 1986; Kuznetov, 2006).
Also, tie to one's ethnic minority groups while being in host country or in a
foreign area was viewed by Sheffer (1986) as a key element of local
intervention of migrant internationally considered as notables.
Chapter two: METHODOLOGY
Ranged as second chapter of this work, the research
methodology presents the foundation of the research issues. That is, the
universe is defined in advance, follows techniques employed to collect data,
presentation of the research questionnaire, variable measure and methods used
to transform them into meaningful outcomes.
I. DEFINITION OF THE POPULATION
Aiming at assessing willingness to pay of the notability for
local leadership empowerment in rural areas, this research concerns only the
«notables» living in town but originating from the rural Chiefdom of
Ngweshe. Thus, as already stated above, is defined for the purpose as member of
the research universe, it means as notable, every male or female individual
recognized as famous or distinctive in their profession through their knowhow
and good manners, originating from Ngweshe chiefdom, at least eighteen years
old and residing in one of the communes of Bukavu on September 1st,
2019.
This manner of descripting the population has as advantage to
avoid including periodically arriving chiefdom folks. It is likely about
maximizing the chance to meet those who can will to participate to the
scheme.
II. SAMPLING TECHNIQUE AND DATA
COLLECTION
The research will apply data collected on a sample of 180
notables issued from Ngweshe. Two techniques will allow realizing that step
given as follows:
Ø A qualitative survey using the interview technique
Ø A Snowball technique
II.1.The qualitative
technique
As above-mentioned, the research universe includes notables
living in Bukavu town. The interview then will be applied to identify the
structure of contributions of notables towards their chiefdom of origin.
Qualitative data collection refers to Abdullah and Jeanty (2011) requirements
relative to setting hypothetical scenarios of WTP amounts. The interview has
taken five days that to say from August 18 to August 26, 2019. In its core
fulfillment, it was done since it was discovered that no supplementary
information was brought by additional respondents accordingly to the semantic
saturation criterion7(*).
Thus, 20 respondents selected from Ibanda, Kadutu and Bagira were interviewed.
Seven questions were directly asked to notables about what leaders think about
local leadership in their chiefdom, who are those leaders, what do they think
about their work, their thoughts regarding leaders' contribution for local
development, how do they think to help local leaders, who should support them
and lastly whether mutuality can help them.
II.2. The snowball technique
The technique is mainly chosen because it is quite difficult
to identify among several individuals those emerging from the Chiefdom of
Ngweshe. Additionally, meeting notable remains very difficult regarding their
availability and location. A chain-referral-sample or respondent-driven
technique is suggested by Etikan et al. (2015) in case of a hidden population.
The city is diversified and thus the research wants to avoid resulting errors
of respondent selection what can since misshape the research outcomes. Thereby,
the first questioned subject shall be a surely identified individual based on
information provided by aNgweshe native lecturer. A deep verification of their
identity shall be verified through a qualitative talk realized on the subject
to be insured that he is exactly a rural citizen who currently is living in
Bukavu. To do so, a five minutes speech is undertaken in the Mashi language
which is the local language in the native chiefdom. In addition, some cultural
values were discussed to assess whether he is well accustomed to traditional
living style (a specific feature of countryside originals).
II.3. The questionnaire
To fulfill this research, two kinds of questionnairewill be
administrated to notables. The first shall be shortened covering the
qualitative survey opened-responded. By the means of the preceeding, a hard
quantitative questionnaire shall thenceafter be administrated to respondents
using referendum-type questions. These kinds of questions are closed-responded.
Hereon in reference to Labii (2015) who used a closed question category in her
research.
II.4. Measuring variables
Dependent variable
The research uses eleven predictors to estimate willingness to
pay. It is made of two core regression as said above. The first is regressed on
independent variables to hold the determinants of willingness to pay of
notables. The second is a no-independent variable regression that helps to
capture WTP in reference to Corso et al. (2013) and Labii (2015).
Therefore, the «amount willed to be
paid» by a notable is measured by the means of recurrent
bids proposing intervals of amounts with lower start to high amounts. Answering
to these questions connotes moving through dummy answers with 1 if an
investigated notable accepts to pay an amount inclusively belonging to that
interval and 0 otherwise. In fact, Bishop and Heberlein (1979) is the reference
for dummy using.8(*)
Therefore, respondents are asked whether they would be willing to pay or not a
particular amount to acquire a change in local governance and development in
the native chiefdom. The technique is also called «take it or leave
it» or referendum. Then the variable is divided into two variables
representing the inferior boundary and the superior boundary of one's interval
inside which can be located his WTP Corso et al. (2013) and Labii (2015).
Independent variables
Various variables are selected inn the research to be tested
on WTP. Downwards are given the way they were measured in the research.
Age of the notable: age plays a key
role in the determination ones acceptance to participate. it is a continuing
variable used to measure the notable's age. It is as well closed some intervals
of years mainly propelled by the fact that notables from countryside to town
likely get famous and wealth towards years. In that vein, some conclusive
studies on willingness to pay found a mean age around an interval of 35 and 50
years (Ajayi, 2006; Gimba and Kumshe, 2011; Miwoto et al., 2017). Moving closer
fifties implies as well nearing retirement and formally active age is left.
Hence, a positive sign is watched.
Household size: to capture it, the
number of individuals under the respondent is used in the survey.
Sex: a qualitative variable with two
modalities. It takes 0 as value to mean female and 1 if the respondent is male.
Marital status: is a
socio-demographic polytomous variable assessing to which category of marital
status belongs the respondent. It takes 1 if the respondent is single, 2 if he
is married, 3 if he is divorced and 4 if the respondent is a widow.
Educational level: it is captured as
a qualitative variable. That is, the variable «level of education» is
polytomous; it proposes different levels of education starting from none to
academic level. Level of education has demonstrated important added-values on
development through innovation and knowledge applied differently comparing to
non-educated individuals (Borjas, 2016). Then, this research aims at estimating
how it could influence one's acceptance to pool in direction of Ngweshe
chiefdom.
Religion: is a qualitative variable
assessing the religious obedience of notables. It also has been set numerous
modalities. Therefore, 1 translates Catholic obedience, 2 is Protestant, 3
Muslim 4 Kimbanguist and 5 other religion. It is used in the regression as a
socio-demographic variable. But aftrer data collection, only two modalities
were retained: Catholic and protestant; others did not record any observation.
Friends in the organization: a
qualitative variable dichotomized. It takes 1 as value if there is at least one
friend in the organization and 0 otherwise.
Number of persons of notoriety: this
variable is quantitative revealing the number of persons the respondent finds
of high notoriety.
Duration in town: duration in town
captures for how long a notable has last in Bukavu. It is a continuous
quantitative variable expressed in years spent in the city.
Membership of the organization: the
variable is qualitative. It is measured using a dichotomic bid. Thus, it is
labeled 0 if the respondent is not member or 1 otherwise.
Notable's monthly income: a
continuous quantitative variable captured using the monthly earned income by
the notable from different sectors in which they directly or indirectly find
some interest. It also takes into account monthly income got from donation.
Trust on local leadership: the
variable capture whether notables trust in local leaders. It takes 0 if the
investigated notable does not trust or 1 if contrastingly he does. The variable
is applied depending on the literature deeming a true confidence between all
the partners so as each one perfectly and favorably act on their common goal.
In the present case, local leaders should be entrusted to incite notables
pooling.
Number of organizations: a
quantitative variable capturing in how many groups or organization a notable
partakes. It only takes into account the kind of organization where people only
aim at realizing some advancement in their societies. So to say, the kinds of
groups or organizations call for social brainstorming.
Index of assets
The index of assets is generated in the purpose of quantifying
assets owned by respondents. For 26 assets captured by the investigation, the
factor analysis shall be used to extract specific values to balance assets
variables through the Principal Component Analysis. Doing so, this work
inspired from Labii (2015) Thus, the below table (see Appendix 1)
walks through those values. Accordingly, the extraction value was considered as
multiplies of each of initial variables of assets. Lastly, were summed all
generated variable building then an «asset index». Feunou (2002) and
Booysen et al. (2008) advise to include in the analysis even assets whose
weight is low for they represent a share of the real assets of an individual.
Set price in the referendum: a
quantitative variable. It is applied to know the annual minimum amount in USD
declared by the notables who engage themselves to tackle diverse social
problems in the chiefdom of Ngweshe.
Grouping selected for scheme: a
qualitative variable measured as a proxy variable whose value is 1 if the
respondent's native grouping is selected to implement a development project
while the value is void 0 if not. This variable is retained in the research
because it has been thought evident that people living out from their native
community mostly remain in touch with their community. This collaboration and
tie to native homelands has allowed lots of billions dollars flowing from
hosting countries to homelands. People have, over and above that argument, a
larger tie as closer as a community is taking as begin his own family. That is,
a positive sign is watched since bid 1 refers to native grouping.
III. Model specification of
willingness to pay
To measure WTP, this paper uses the contingent valuation
method consisting of directly asking respondents the amount they are disposed
to pay for a potential scenario of improving local leadership aiming for
instance at fighting against its disappearance or to anticipate its damageable
parts. It is an enquiry-based method frequently used to measure the monetary
value on non-market environmental good and services (Djemaci, 2010). Here, the
method is set on a referendum enquiry.
The method «contingent valuation» requires that
replies recorded follow a bidding scenarios process. Proposed scenarios are
possible but not certain to occur since they vary from an individual to
another. Contingent valuation entails a change in the notable's utility that
can be monetary valued and obtained by the maximum amount that a respondent
accepts to forgo for achieving a given good. Le Gall-Ely (2010) views CVM as a
surveying method helping to capture some psychological price. In such a case,
deems Le Gall-Ely (2010), biases are higher resulting from an overestimation of
WTP. However, previous scholars suggest that questions referring to starting
price have yielded more considerable results than open-ended questions
(Donaldson et al., 1997) cited by Dror, Radermacher and Koren et al. (2006).
«Take-it-or-leave-it» method is basically viewed as a dichotomous
trade-off on suggested amounts. In fact, Dong et al. (2004) deemed that
variance in responses results from some extent from the selection by
respondents. The biding game consisting of presenting several prices varying
from relatively higher to lower prices and the respondent choses if he is ready
to pay a given set biding price, a process realized on all alternatives until
the respondent accepts the bid.
Moreover, the interval regression method was applied to assess
WTP in various WTP assessment studies. In that boat it is used to estimate
hypothetical values of the real goods or/and services (Lang, 2010). The method
as developed by Hanemann is advised when the correlation coefficient exceeds
0,7 (Alberini, 1995) instead of the bivariate probit model initially
established to measure WTP. It is set on the response between the first and the
second bid (Corso et al., 2013; Labii, 2015).
As dummy questions are asked in the survey, it is suggested an
amount to an individual. If the individual accepts to disburse under that
price, a higher amount is directly advanced for his trade-off. On the other
hand, if he rejected the first bid, then a lower amount is immediately proposed
under his trade-off.
Furthermore, based on how the model was specified by Corso et
al. (2013) when assessing the benefits of preventing child maltreatment death
in Ecuadorian population and, also, its adoption by Labii (2015);the current
research model evolves as follows:
The WTP value, of individual is translated by the model where is a random disturbing term and normally distributed with a mean zero
(hypothetical) and corresponds to individual respondent characteristics. As is not direclty observed, the respondent's WTP interval location lies
between both bounds . Then, the corresponding likelihood contribution becomes:
(1)
When an upper bound is unknown, that is the right-censored
data is unknown; the likelihood affected is
(2)
Whereas when a lower bound (left-censored), a lower bound is
set at zero and the likelihood contribution is:
(3)
From there is taken out a summarizing situation of all
possibilities to be registered over the bids. Four patterns are classified from
the dichotomous trade-off: «Yes» to both the first and the second
question (Y, Y), «Yes» to the first question and «No» to
the second proposing a higher amount(Y,N); «No» to the first and
«Yes» to the second (N,Y), in case the lower value, and
«No» to both values (N,N).
Scenarios imply the following likelihood distribution
according to measuring WTP. But before proceeding, let's assume an individual
to whom is fist propose an amount . If admitted, a higher amount is again proposed. In contrast, if the first was not accepted, a lower
amount is then advanced.
Ø When both answers are positive, that is to say that
the individual 's willingness to payis higher than Differently said, the superior bound is unknown; data are
right-censured and the likelihood ( ) noticed that their WTP to be located in the interval is
Ø If then the first answer is positive and the second
negative (accounting for the upper bound), willingness to pay is located
between the lower bound and the upper bound. And the associated likelihood is given by
Ø Therewith, if the first answer is no and the second
no to both bids, one's willingness to pay is under and the likelihood to
Ø At last, when the individual answers no to the first and yes to the second, it means his maximum WTP
is located between and In the context, the likelihood of locating WTP in the interval is given
by .
IV. Data processing technique
After having a database, results are processed using the STATA
software. Especially the command intregwas twice applied to produce
econometric outcome in respect to Williams' (2019) requirement concerning
interval data. The first regression involves both parts of the dependent
variable9(*) (WTP) and the
independent variables successively applying a stepwise process on three models:
the first takes into account socio-demographic variables, the second involves
variables on social capital and the third incorporates other economic and
environmental variables. It allows seizing the determinants of WTP. The second
regression is only applied on dependent variables and helps so as the value of
WTP become recognized.
Chapter three: RESULT PRESENTING
AND INTERPRETATION
The current chapter presents the core outcomes of the
research. It goes beyond the step of surveying the several members of the
research universe who no longer were selected in the sample. It initially
gives general descriptive information on the population characteristics and
then goes out with results related to models associated to extract the core
message of the analyses.
I. GENERAL FEATURES OF NOTABLES
Table two: Descriptive statistics on notables and
their households
|
N
|
Minimum
|
Maximum
|
Average
|
Std. Deviation
|
Household size
|
180
|
3
|
15
|
8,02
|
2,520
|
DURA_MEBERSH
|
180
|
0
|
39
|
8,94
|
6,564
|
Duration in town
|
180
|
10
|
49
|
27,37
|
8,180
|
Notable monthlyincome
|
180
|
100
|
8000
|
1864,72
|
1442,431
|
Total household expenditure
|
180
|
24532.98
|
14836.2
|
7450
|
82168
|
Valid N (listwise)
|
180
|
|
|
|
|
Source: own primary data processed in SPSS/ 20
Results of the descriptive statistics help to capture
notables' characteristics. In that concern, the table reveals diverse
tendencies. The variable «Age» of the notable records a mean value of
55,51 years old; nearly the Congolese life expectancy.10(*) The youngest of them is 40
whereas the oldest is 68 years old. On average, they have dwelled in Bukavu
for 27.4 years. The minimum duration found is 10 although 49 is the maximal
duration. The results also empirically attest that a notable has lasted as
member of a group 8,944 (around 9 years). Moreover, there are beginners with
any year experiencing groups or organizations and former organization attenders
who at most passed (years under organizations. Their monthly revenue is on
average USD 1864,72 varying from 100 to USD 8000.
The size of notables' household recorded respectively 3 and 15
as minimum and maximum effective. But for the whole, household members recorded
an average of 8,02with a weak standard deviation of 2,5203.
About their monthly income, each notable acquires per month
USD 1864,72; a mean value of their respective monthly smoothed incomes. In
addition, there is an impressive gap in their incomes. That is, an important
dispersion of USD 1442,431 can be caught as a proof of an undeniable inequality
in notable's income. Indeed, the variable notable's monthly income records
respectively 100 and 8000 as the smallest and terminal values. Watching the
ampleness reflected by this wide from the variable's average, a certain
analysis on the way this disbursement will be accomplished seem overlooked. As
it can be realized, the interval issued from analysis is round USD 20 and USD
1500. Besides, expenditure annually engaged by notables' household meet an
average of USD24532.98 but it is denoted, however, that expendute largly varies
from the mean across notables. Watching the standard deviation with deep
attention, a value of USD 14836.2 not only has shown a certain wide existing in
that trend but leads to inspecting the size throught which this dispersion is
located. As it can be attessted from the table, total annual expenditure of
notables' households varies from a minimum of 7450 and a maximum of USD 82168.
FREQUENCES ON NOTABLES' FEATURES VARIABLES
The distribution of frequencies is applied on qualitative
variables. It therefore takes into account the central tendency measure of the
independent variables downwards involved in the econometric model. Frequency
distribution has depended on how were allowed occurencesmodalities. The
following illustrative table is drawn belowexposed.
Table three: Frequency distribution of qualitative
distribution
Variable
|
Modality
|
Frequency
|
Percent
|
Cumulative Percent
|
Grouping of origine
|
IKOMA
|
12
|
6,7
|
6,7
|
IRONGO
|
9
|
5,0
|
11,7
|
IZEGE
|
11
|
6,1
|
17,8
|
KAMANYOLA
|
16
|
8,9
|
26,7
|
KAMISIMBI
|
10
|
5,6
|
32,2
|
KANIOLA
|
14
|
7,8
|
40,0
|
LUBONA
|
10
|
5,6
|
45,6
|
LUCIGA
|
8
|
4,4
|
50,0
|
LURHALA
|
11
|
6,1
|
56,1
|
MULAMBA
|
11
|
6,1
|
62,2
|
MUSHINGA
|
12
|
6,7
|
68,9
|
MUZINZI
|
9
|
5,0
|
73,9
|
NDUBA
|
3
|
1,7
|
75,6
|
NYANGEZI
|
6
|
3,3
|
78,9
|
RUBIMBI
|
12
|
6,7
|
85,6
|
WALUNGU
|
26
|
14,4
|
100,0
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Dwelling place
|
Bagira
|
3
|
1,7
|
1,7
|
Kadutu
|
40
|
22,2
|
23,9
|
Ibanda
|
137
|
76,1
|
100,0
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Sex
|
Female
|
49
|
27,2
|
27,2
|
Male
|
131
|
72,8
|
100,0
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Educationallevel
|
None
|
5
|
2,8
|
2,8
|
Primary
|
11
|
6,1
|
8,9
|
Secondary
|
76
|
42,2
|
51,1
|
Academic
|
88
|
48,9
|
100
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Marital status
|
Single
|
1
|
0,6
|
0,6
|
Married
|
151
|
83,9
|
84,4
|
Widow
|
28
|
15,6
|
100,0
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Accommodation
|
Semi-durable
|
8
|
4,4
|
4,4
|
Durable
|
172
|
95,6
|
100,0
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Member of an organization
|
No
|
10
|
5,6
|
5,6
|
Yes
|
170
|
94,4
|
100,0
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Status in the household
|
Head
|
142
|
78,9
|
78,9
|
Spouse
|
37
|
20,6
|
90,4
|
Other
|
1
|
0,6
|
100
|
Total
|
180
|
100,0
|
|
Source: own primary data processed in Stata 14.0.
Seven variables were taken in the frequency analysis. No void
value was recorded as is shown in the above table. Statistics set upwards the
distribution of frequencies for each of them. Thereby, for 180 surveyed
individuals, it is demonstrated that they are unequally distributed in the
three communes of Bukavu. Therefore, Ibanda is the most dwelt by 76,1% of
notables whereas Bagira lodges only by 1,7% percent of the whole. As for
Kadutu, only 40 notables rising 22,2% of records are found to accommodate in
the commune. For the whole, 49 are female representing 27,2 % of the total
while 72,8 % were male. The results imply that men are numerous in the
notables' group nominee FondsCommunautaire pour la Rehabilitation de
Ngweshe (FCRN).They show an extreme score of educational level. In fact,
48,9% have acquired an academic level ad 42,2% were schooled at secondary
school. Put together, 91,1% have at least attended the secondary school. And
only 5 people out of 180 were not schooled what represents only 2, 8% of the
population. Therewith, 11 reached the primary school accounting for 6,1%. This
in fact can be an intuitive explanation of the presence of an ideology
attempting to boost local development in the native chiefdom. The more people
are skilled the more they are sensitive to future challenges and anticipate
disasters rather than staying by them.
A large number as well is made of heads of their households; a
proportion of 142 notables belong to the status representing 78,9% of the whole
followed by the category of spouses accounting for 37 notables and translating
approximately 21% of the whole. Only one individual didn't belong to both
categories. As for their accommodation, 172 out of 180 notables live in
durable buildings forming 95,6% of respondents and only 8 of them live in
semi-durable houses as well translating 4,4% of the total. All the notables are
further Christians dispatched into two categories. The Catholic category scores
71,7% of the total size namely 129 individuals. Moreover, 51 individuals are
protestants accounting for 28,3% . Although only Christians take share to
pooling local authorities in the chiefdom, about ¾ of notables are
catholic believers and only ¼ are Protestants.
II. RELATED ECONOMETRIC ESTIMATE OF
THE MODEL
The econometric model is twice computed. Once it is regressed
as further above mentioned in the methodology to generate the determinants of
WTP and second is computed a self-dependent variable to generate the amount of
WTP. Determinants of WTP are first given by the below table.
II.2. Determinants of WTP towards
Ngweshe local leadership
Table four: determinants of WTP
Variable Model1.
Model 2 Model 3
|
_cons -344.4466
-408.9637 -1065.497**
(445.3187)
(443.4349) (474.7537)
Age 5.778969
3.475518 -.9431211
(5.804049)
(5.831309) (7.199842)
Household size 6.901429
8.008575 5.315404
(14.55212)
(14.37865) (14.95299)
Sex 47.89076
43.65722 -47.09211
(93.41336)
(92.87509) (91.01455)
Marital status 15.96233
27.43283 27.21543
(57.93045)
(58.68485) (56.47982)
Educational level
Primary 393.4607
521.014*** 508.8818 ***
(258.7015)
(269.8894) (261.6663)
Secondary 368.3236***
404.5382*** 371.4343 ***
(222.6376)
(221.6682) (225.2885)
Academic 468.3764**
502.0473** 499.3925 **
(225.8814)
(223.7823) (216.8748)
Religion -36.23913
-9.671601 -68.94029
(82.88123)
(82.93868) (78.7152)
Friends in the organization
22.66025 106.1979
(98.08002) (102.4303)
Num_persons of notoriety
25.86194** 24.23693 **
(12.28004) (11.74927)
Duration in town
5.7078
(5.973686)
Membership of an organi.
100.6749
(154.5649)
Notable monthly income.
0770756 **
(9.0321531)
Trust in local leaders
-110.7046 ***
(67.00494)
Number of organization
40.35309
(37.71582)
Index of asset
190.7712 **
(91.48116)
Set price amount
.1299662
(.3877647)
Important sch. in grouping
31.93639
(78.61212)
|
Wald chi2 6.62
(0.5782) 11.16 (0.3452) 43.20
(0.0008)
|
**And *** respectively Significant at 5and
10%.
|
Source: own primary data process in Stata 14.0.
II.2.1. Interpretation of findings
As for predictor variables, the model bares that they
approximately all come closer to positively affect notables' WTP except
variable «trust in local leaders». After introducing controlling
variables in using a stepwise process, five variables are found significant.
They are Educational level, the Number of persons of notoriety in the notables'
organization, notable monthly income, trust in local leaders, and index of
assets.
Educational level is found favourable to WTP. Applied stepwise
generation has displayed three categories built on an educational scale. In
that context, notables with primary level have expressed a higher level than
notables whose educational level was secondary school. It should be noticed,
however, that both trends positively influence WTP towards local leadership.
Moreover, outcomes on the variable deem that notables with academic level
present the highest - of the variable's categories - and significant WTP at
0.05 considering its Wald test. Dror, Radermacher and Koren et al. (2006) have
also found similar trends when assessing WTP for health insurance among rural
and poor person except primary school which was tested adverse.
Notwithstanding, WTP of respondents from 11th class and beyond was
significant and positive. As for Gnimassoun and Anyanwu (2019), their work
confirms that the most Africa will deliver educated migrants; the greater the
impact of diaspora will be experienced across the continent. Other scholars
like Djemaci (2010), Lang (2010), Miwoto et al. (2017) or Houaga (2017) approve
the result. Better is also to view in the outcome a contrasting result with
Bhagwati and Hamada (1974) who professed that brain drain weakens and loses
hope of the rural concerned region.
In the same boat, «monthly income» is investigated
to slightly improve WTP and significant at 0.05. Around USD 0.077 for each
additional dollar earned is consented to be given. Notables are furthermore
affected by their network inside the group. Thus, the most the number of
persons judged of notoriety will raise WTP will as well grow. In contrast,
«Trust in leadership» deeply adversely and meaningfully bears
notables' willingness to pay (a drop of USD 110.70). In another view,
leadership translates a setback toitsown improvement. Kuznetsov (2006) deems
that the most important aspect of remittances is not financial transfers;
governance and monitoring are. Community infrastructure projects need to be
identified, financed, and managed through a network of diverse stakeholders -
municipal government, users of the infrastructure, migrants and others - that
previously had little trust in one another. Torres and Kuznetsov (2001) made
efforts in better use of the receipts. The number of persons of notoriety in
the notables' organization is furthermore favourable to contribution from
notables to the chiefdom's local leadership. It is indirectly to say bearing
local development in the region throught local administration. In the above
table, a mere look at the variable's coefficient persuades one to confirm an
addition of USD 24,24 in one's WTP in case of any supplementary person of
notoriety.
The variable «index of assets» is a
positive predictor. It reflects the wealth value translated in terms of assets
that each notable owns. Besides, outcomes translate a rise of USD
190.77whenever an additional per cent is added on notables' assets. Labii
(2015) previously denoted that the index of assets was positively but not
significantly tied to WTP. So said, the research confirms exactly that index of
assets is one of the impeccable determinants in the process of pooling over the
chiefdom of Ngweshe.
II.2.2. Correlation matrix
The correlation matrix denotes a weak correlation regarding
most independent variables taken one another and their correlation with the
dependent variable. They all are largely inferior to 0.5 except the correlation
between «duration in Town» and «age». Also there is a very
high correlation between both boundaries of the interval variable
«WTP». It is a mere translation of what exactly should be the trend
of both sub-dependent variables. As a unique variable computed in respect to
the principal of two side formalization, boundaries must exactly show a perfect
correlation as a proof of the rightness of one variable. Otherwise an absence
convergence would be reputed between both sub-variables. Since, it could be a
proof that results are sidestepped. As further bellow pointed (Appendix 2),
their correlation is 0,9792 what is exactly closer to 1. Additionally,
there is absence of multicollinearity. The relevance from the matrix is
minimized correlations once between the dependent and independent variables
ultimately nearby 0. For Instance, correlation between variable Trust in local
leaders and both WTP is 0 for the left boundary and 0.0042 for the right
boundary. What is right perceived as an almost neutral mutual influence in the
collection of both variables. Others variables observe the same trend as it is
typically highlighted in the matric. For instance, the value of correlation of
setting price amount and membership of an organization is 0,0050. Above and
beyond such essential validity of the quality of the data specification is
added up a new regression measuring WTP towards local leadership in the
chiefdom of Ngweshe.
II.2.3. Assessment of the mean WTP
Table five: Capture of WTP value
Interval regression
Number of obs = 180
Log likelihood = -457.07099
LR chi2(0) = 0.00
Prob> chi2 = .
|
Coef. Z P>|z|
[95% Conf. Interval
|
_cons 443.6262 12.27
0.000 372.7546 514.4978
|
Source: Source: own primary data process in Stata
14.0.
The overhead table reveal that the avearage amount notables
are willing to yearly pay for local development through local leaders
performance is USD 443.63. The interval reveals USD 372.76 and USD 514.50 as
respectively minimum and maximum WTP. The Wald test is very higher (Z=12.27) to
which is tied a meaningful likelihood (P>|z|= 0.000). Descriptive statistics
have demonstrated upwards that the mean monthly income of a notable is USD
1864,72. It is thus understandable the amount found can be yearly consented and
issued.
II.3. Discussion and social
implication of findings
The model has helped to come out determinants of WTP and
further the amount translating notables' WTP. That is,the following variables
namely level of education, the number of persons of notoriety in the
organization, notables' monthly income, trust in leadership and index of assets
are found significant to deteermine financial contributionfor developmental
actions across Ngweshe chiefdom. In fact, increasingly group participators are
educated notables, WTP will rise. The research outcome on variable educational
level is more decisive for academic level in providing a meaningful insight to
permanently schooling new generations in colleges and universities. It also
shows that additional schooling level could present a higher likelihood to
register ulterior significant income which likewise is a positive and
significant determinant of Willingness to Pay especially for the academic
level. But, as the chiefdom does not have comfortable institutions, namely
colleges and universities, the trend will always lead to rural exodus of the
youth - as it is currently remarked - in search of faithful institutions and
studies.
Since, rural-urban movement of the youth maintains an
attention on what lose leaving workforce implies in terms of local
productivity. Like external migration, internal migration of the active youth
is incited by the search of employment and decent revenues (World Bank and
CRES, 2009).Here raises a retrospective analysis on migration in the chiefdom's
nearest city of Bukavu mostly frequented by peasant students. The most of
times, in fact, they use to finding jobs and remain jobless in the city rather
tnan immediately goind back to their country to put into effect, together with
the altogether folks, schemes tied to durable development. Dashing off has
accordingly been a continuous setback in construction to rural development
(Bhagwati and Hamada, 1974) likely covered in long run when already realizing
some return to schooling in the host area (Nishikant and Priyanka, 2018).
Undetr this motivation lie many factors discouraging students to return to
their fatherland of which a painful living standard comparatively to the city
and a high lack of infrascture. The drop of agricultural labour force it
implies, for instance, would count against countryside capacity to produce
crops or lessen somer locally-engaged communal work like sanitation, security,
etc. Even though, good news is that these former students further participate
intpo the group of notables of the region when success has come their way in
the abovementionned city? Brainstrming is exalted to notables of all kind of
profession to think, decide and realize together some big push to tackle a few
challenges worsening living conditions through the local chieftaincy. They
involve sectors like health, agriculture, infrastructure, etc. People will to
give as many as the group registers new persons of notoriety; especially
economicly stronger. In that vein, developing a strong social network inside
the native notables is a huge step to get all of them involved in the program.
Although they financially differ in teerms of wealth, relative small owners
have care encouraged to pay when prosperous people also participate.
Moreover, reinforcing local leadership and through them local
development in the chiefdom of Ngweshe calls consistent means to notables. The
present empirical results demonstrate that montly income of the notability
favourably plays a role in the amount they will to pay. It is in fact probative
because they could't pool whether their wealth is so mild that it couldn't
allow them living.
Not only that the variable montly income is confidently
significant at 95% but also the amount it translates gives a reamlistic hope.
For any dollar monthly earned by the notable, USD 0,077 is consented like
allowance to local leaders' developmental actions. It is then necessary to
understand that in the present case, income depends on several resources
bearing their active life. Thereof, futher policies can directly act on the
capacity of notables to deliver funds. If the running macroeconomic policies
jeapardize people's purchasing power and lessens their demand, for instance, in
general notables shall face a decrease in their income especially traders may
be the most affected.
Macroeconomic aggregations in DRC should hence abide for the
economic stabilization. In light of the above table, accessing to significant
income helps notables to realize some expenditure. In the purpose, one
meaningful of them is getting assets. Acquiring them requires means. Though it
seems intuitively less tied to Willingness to pay, it is however favourable and
meaningful to the level of WTP. There is anyway a huge correlation between the
notable's monthly income and the level of assets (0.4381) of the notables (see
appendix 2). One should understand at which at extent this kind of
organization is an opportunity to supply a mild if not impact on the chiefdom's
development. As a light to a kind of initiative that can be implemented
nationwide, income should be statble in default of incrieasing to exactly see
poolings rise so to push to communal advancements. This stability involves as
well one's purchasing power tied to the nominal value of owned money in a given
period.
Another reason would result from having expensive and
prestigious assets witness their opulence. For instance, driving a new brand
car costing more than USD 40 000 would be an insight to an individual to make
difference from his fellow notable owning a USD 3 000 car. It may be one of
the motivations of self-categorization of the «FCRN» members
in terms of the amount they're willing to yearly and voluntarily give. Since,
the policy passes as inclusive for a credible mobilization of funds.
Contrastingly, the self-denial demonstrated by notables does
not favourably view the local leadership currently rullingNgweshe. They
criticize the kind of leadership in their decentralized entity. Indeed,
leadership must show a fantastic and permanent accountability so as people
become confident in them and follow what they order. Notice that it is,
however, the only one adverse and significant variable tied to Willingness to
pay toward the chieftaincy of Ngweshe in the model. The quality of leadership
diminishes the amount predisposed of about USD 110.70.
Above and beyond, local leaders have expressed a mean amount
of USD 443.63 in an interval built on USD 372.75 at left and USD 514.50 at
right. These values are set on a likelihood of 95% to happen. From this moment
both bound values are somehow closer to the mean value. The amounts globally
denote a considerable WTP to pay towards local leaders. If the amount comes to
being channelized over the chiefdom and get carefully affected to schemes they
have been planned for, some changes can progressively be initiated.
Accordingly, depending to the whole number of poolers, the level of raises will
determine which kind of scheme is immediately being implemented provided that
it affects in general local development and acts for rural citizens living in
all the groupings of Ngweshe.
CONCLUSION
Pooling toward the chiefdom of Ngweshe remains a useful action
for local leadership survival. Local development of the region appealed for
different sources of resources to thrive as many as challenges have risen over
the recent years. Accordingly, decentralization has not covered the living
conditions of the rural citizens living in the corner. Good news is that
another helping hand has risen composed of the notables to strengthen the
former abilities.
The current assessment ranges over that philanthropic
self-engagement of the notability of Ngweshe living in the town of Bukavu.
Notables have remained strongly tied to their native land and their population
which contains their relatives despite long duration they have spent in Bukavu.
Thus for example they have created communal structures in terms of
brainstorming to think and reshape new forms to hand over Ngweshe. Their
expressed mean willingness to pay is USD 443.63 per year to which is associated
one important conditionviewed as a caution addressed to the leadership of
Ngweshe to improve democratic values in the chiefdom such as transparency,
accountability, management capacity improvement, etc. Moreover, five key
variables are determinants in the motivation to dob in; Educational level, the
number of persons of notoriety in the notables' organization, membership of an
organization, notable monthly income, trust in local leaders, assets
index.While this dissertation lies on population contribution like Ajayi
(2006), Miwoto et al. (2017), Jha and Bhalla (2018) but exploit a bipartite
cooperation in the process, the present work goes through internal migrants
dobbing in for their native chiefdom through local leadership on place. Its
originality, depending to the literature on our disposition, lied in the fact a
bringing a lignt in terms of determinants and amount to a new kind
ofdevelopment support decided through their culture of brainstorming in the
group.
However, it must be recognized, the research encountered lots
of challenges of which of finance being given the space seesaw motion
surounded,a lack of immediat access to notables; reason of giving up the random
method. Also, other natives of the chiefdom currently living in Bukavu would
have been taken into account by the study to assesss the altogether capacity of
thier community to mobilze funds for schemes accomplishment. Thereafter, didn't
exploit the trends and capacities over times or assess the WTA of other
partners called in the programme in the chiefdom.A huge field remains open to
other seekers who would like to exploit these issues.
REFERENCES
Ajayi A. O., (2006), «Willingness to participate in the
financing of agricultural extension services in Oyo state, Nigeria: a factor
analysis», Extension and rural Sociology, Faculty of Agriculture,
ObafemiAwolowoUniverity, Ile-Ife, Journal of Sustainable
Development,Vol. 1. N°2, 2-11.
Ajayi A. R. and Otuya N., (2006), «Women's participation
in self-help community development projects in Ndokwa agricultural zone of
Delta state, Nigeria», Community Development Journal, 41(2),
189-209.
Alberini, (1995), «Efficiency vs bias of willingness to
pay estimates: bivariate and interval-data models», Journal of
environmental economics and statistics 29, 169-80.
Ampa N. R., (2018), «Transparency and accountability
among public sector entities in Bukavu (East of DRC)», masters
dissertation report, Makerere University, No. 2016/HD10/3095X, 1-36.
Arthur J. L., (2005), «Family size and its socio-economic
implications in the Sunyanimunicipaliy of the BrongAhafo», Center for
Development Studies, Faculty of Social Science, University of Cape Coast, Capez
Coast, Ghana.
Balemba K. E., Bucekuderhwa B. C. and Labii K. H., (2018),
«Les determinants du crowdfunding hors ligne: une étude empirique
sur les entrepreneurs et investisseurs potentiels à Bukavu »,
Innovations 2 (n°56), 187-215.
Banque Africaine de Développement and Fonds Africain de
Développement, (2009), « République Démocratique
du Congo : étude économique et sectorielle développement
économique régional au Bas-Congo dans le contexte de la
décentralisation en RDC », département des
opérations par pays, Région Centre.
Bhagwati J. N. and Hamada K., (1974), «The brain drain,
international integration of markets for professionals and unemployment»,
Journal of Development Economics 1, 19-42.
Bliki, S. A., (2011), « Financement de la gestion
des déchets ménagers à Porto-Novo au
Bénin ». Mémoire de fin de formation pour l'obtention
du DEA/Master. UAC.
Boakye P.A. and Béland D., (2018), «Explaining
chieftaincy conflict using historical institutionalism: a case study of the Ga
Mashie chieftaincy in Ghana», African Studies,1 - 20. DOI:
10.1080/00020184.2018.1540531
Bob-Milliar G. M., (2009), «Chieftaincy, diaspora, and
development: the institution of Nkosuohene in Ghana», African Affairs,
108/433, 541 - 558.
Booysen F., Berg S. V. D, Burger R, Maltitz M. V. and Rand G.,
(2008), «Trends in poverty and inequality in seven African
countries», Revised draft report for 2005 PEP meeting 13-17 June, Colombo,
Sri Lanka, P.1-42.
Borjas G.J., (2016), «Labor economics», Havard
University, McGraw-Hill Irwill, third edition, P. 536.
Brinkerhoff J. M., (2008), «The Potential of Diasporas
and Development».
Caldeira E, Foucault M. and Rota-Graziosi G., (2012),
«Decentralization in Africa and the nature of local governance
competition: evidence from Benin», National Bureau of Economic Research,
Working paper 18126, Massachusetts avenue, Cambridge, 1-32.
Carson R. T., (2000), «Contingent Valuation: a user's
guide», Environment Science Technology 2000, 34, 1413-1418.
Casey, J. F., Kahn, J. R., Rivas, A., (2006), «Analysis
willingness to pay for improved water service in Manaus, Amazonas,
Brazil», Ecological Economics 58 (2006) 365- 372.
Center for the study of citizenship, «definition of
citizenship», Wayne State University, College of liberal Arts and
sciences.
Charle C., (1997), « Légitimité en
péril. Eléments pour une histoire comparée des
élites et de l'Etat en France et en Europe occidentale
(XIXe-XXe Siècle) », Actes de la
recherche en sciences sociales, n°116/117 mars, P 39-52.
Chigwata, (2015), «Decentralization in Africa and the
Resilience of Traditional Authorities: Evaluating Zimbabwe's track
record», Regional and Federal studies,
Cohen J.M., Uphoff N.T., (1980), «Participations Place in
Rural Development: Seeking Clarity through Specificity», World
Development, 8: 213-235.
Constitution de la République Démocratique du
Congo, modifié par la loi n°11/ 002 du 20 janvier 2011 p ortant
révision de certains articles de la Constitution de la République
Démocratique du Congo du 18 février 2006 (Textes
coordonnés), Journal Officiel de la République
Démocratique du Congo, Cabinet du président de la
République.
Cortina J, Taran A and Raphael A., (2014), «Migration and
youth: challenges and opportunities», Global Migration Group, UNICEF.
Crook R., (2003), «Decentralization and poverty reduction
in Africa: the politics of local-central relations», Institute of
Development Studies, University of Sussex, Brighton, U, Public Admin. Dev. 23,
77-88.
DFID, «Democratic Republic of the Congo: country
plan», 2008-2010.
Djemaci B., (2010), « Les déterminants du
consentement à payer pour améliorer pour améliorer les
services de gestion des déchets municipaux en Algérie : ces
de la ville des Issers », Les cahiers du CREAD, n°92, P. 43-65.
Dong H, Mugisha F, Gbangou A, Kouyate B, Sauerborn R., (2004),
«The feasibility of community-based health insurance in Burkina
Faso». Health Policy, 69(1):45-53.
Dror, Radermacher and Koren, (2006), «Willingness to pay
for health insurance among rural and poor persons: Field evidence from seven
micro health insurance units in India», Health Policy.
doi:10.1016/j.healthpol.2006.07.011
Duberstein and Steiguer, (2003), «Contingent Valuation
and Watershed Management: A Review of Past Uses and Possible Future
Applications». 748-753.
Englebert P. and Kasongo E. M., (2016), «Misguiding and
misdiagnosed: The failure of Decentralization Reforms in DR Congo»,
African study review, vol. 59, Issue 1, 5-32.
Erk J., (2018), «Comparative territorial politics in
Sub-saharan Africa», Comparative territorial politics in Sub-Saharan
Africa, a handbook of territorial politics,354-370.
Etikan L., Alkassim R., and Abubakar S., (2015),»
Comparison of snowball sampling and and sequential sampling Technique»,
Biometrics and Biostatistics International Journal, Vol.3 (1),00055.
DOI: 10.15406/bbij.2015.03.00055
FAO, (2018), «The state of food and agriculture:
Migration, agriculture and rural development».
Fiszbein A., 1997, The emergence of local capacity: lessons
from Colombia, The World Bank, Washington D.C.? USA, Vol.25, N°
7, 1029-1043.
Fonta W. M., Ichoku H. E. and Nwosu E., (2011),
«Contingent valuation in community-based project planning: the case of
lake Bamendjim fishery restocking in Cameroon», African Economic Research
Consortium, Nairobi, P.36.
Forth S., What shapes willingness to pay (WTP), may 2018.
Ganta C. V. and Manukonda J. K., (2014), «Leadership
during change and uncertainty in organizations», Organizational
Behavior and Management Perspective 3(3): 1183.
Gaynor N., (2014), «Challenges of decentralization in the
Democratic Republic of the Congo: Beyond the political settlement»,
Journal of International Development, School of Law and Government,
Dublin City University, Dublin, Ireland, p1-16, DOI: 10.1002/jid.3046.
Gimba Z. and Kumshe M. G., (2011), «Causes and effects of
rural-urban migration in Borno state: a case study of Maiduguri
metropolis», Asiatic Journal of Business and Maanagement
Sciences, Vol.1, 168-172;
Gnimassoun B. and Anyanwu J. C., (2019), «The diaspora
and economic development in Africa», African Development Bank Group,
Working paper series, n°308.
Haddak M. M., Havet N. and Lefèvre M. (2014),
«Willingness-to-pay for road saafety improvement».
Halshs-00950017.
Hall D., Kyle Osland K., Fowler S., Mullen K., Audet M., Keane
K., Clarkhtmnd M. and DeFrancisco J., (2015), «The power of local
leadership», Leadership conference essays 2015 McDonald cadet leadership
conference, The News York Times in Education.
Hanemann W.M., (1989) «Willingness to pay and willingness
to accept: how much can they differ», Department of Agricultural and
Resource Economics, California Agricultural Experiment Station, University of
California, working paper n° 328. 1-27.
Houaga P. R., (2017), « Evaluation de la diffusion
et du consentement à payer pour les formations par vidéo des
transformatrices de Soja en Fromage à Tchaourou »,
mémoire de Master Professionnel, Université de Parakou,
Inédit.
Huque A. S., (2014), «Local leadership: development,
problems and potential in Bangladesh», The Asian Pacific Journal of
Public Administration, Vol.29, n°2,223-239.
ILO, (2019), «Why do young people migrate?» UN
International Youthday. Available on
www.ilo/global/about-the-ilo/newsroom/comment-analysis/WCMS_219045/lang-en/index.htm
Islam M. H., Bhuiyan M. S. and Salam M. F., (2019),
«Strengthening local government through participation and
leadership», Journal of Public Administration and Policy
Research, Vol.11(2) PP. 56611. DOI/ 10.5897/JPAPR2019.0444.
Jha P. J. and Bhalla A., (2018), «Life of a PAI:
mediation by willingness and ability for beneficiary community
engagement», World Development Perspectives 9, 27-34.
Jin, M., (2013), «Does social cantal quality and social
capital influence in Sweden.FAERE», Working Paper, 2016.13.
JMDIMD, (2011), «A bottom-up approach». A handbook
for practitioners and policymakers. Find on:
http://www.globalmigrationgroup.org/uploads/UNCT_Corner/theme7/jmdi_august_2011_handbook_migration_for_development.pdf
Jones, N., Malesios, C. and Sophoulis, C.M., (2008),
«Economic valuation of coastal water quality and protest responses: a case
study in Mitilini, Greece», Journal of Socio-Economics 37(6):
2478-2491.
Khan M. M., (2012), «Functioning of local Governments
(Union Prishad): Legal and Practical Constraints», Department of Public
Administration, University of Dhaka.
Khan S. H., (1999), «United they survive: Redistribution,
leadership and human services delivery in rural Bangladesh».
Kuznetsov Y., (2006), «Diaspora networks and the
international migration of skills: how countries can draw on their talent
abroad», the World Bank, Washington DC, P. 237.
Lai H., (2010), «Uneven opening of China's Society,
Economy and Politics: Pro-growth authoritarian Governance and protests in
China», Journal of Contemporary China, Vol 19 (67): 819-835.
Lang H-c, (2010), «Willingness to pay for Lung cancer
treatment», International Society for Pharmacoeconomics and Outcomes
Research, National Yang-Ming University, Vol. 13, 743-749.
Le Gall-Ely M., (2010), «Definition, Measurement and
Determinants of the Consumer's Willingness to Pay: a Critical Synthesis and
Directions for Further Research», Rechercheet Applications en
Marketing (French Edition), SAGE Publications, 24 (2), pp.91-113.
Macias, T. and Williams, K., (2014), «Know your
neighbors, save the planet: Social capital and the widening wedge of
pro-environmental outcomes», Environment and Behavior, 1-30.
Marbuah G., (2016), «Willingness to pay for environmental
quality and social capital influence in Sweden», French Association of
Environmental and resource Economists, Working Paper.13.
Martinez-Vazquez J. and Vaillancourt F., (2011),
«Obstacles to Decentralization: Lessons from the Developing World»,
An Overview of the Main Obstacle to Decentralization.
Marysse S. L., (2005), «Decentralization issues in
post-conflict Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC)», Afrique des
GrandsLacs, Annuaire 2005.
Masango M., (2002), «Leadership in the African
context», in Verbum et ecclesia.
Maswana, J-C., (2018), « Développement
économique et sécurité en République
démocratique du Congo », Etudes Africaines,
Série Economie, l'Harmattan.
Matraia A., Giacaman, R., Khatib, R., &Moatti, Jean-Paul,
(2006), «Impoverishment and patients' willingness and ability to pay for
improving the quality of health care in Palestine: An assessment using the
contingent valuation method», Health Policy, 75(3), 312-328.
Miwoto M, Zannou A and Biaou G, (2017),
« Déterminants des montants de consentement à payer
(CAP) déclarés par les ménages pour une gestion durable de
la forêt d'Adjamey au Sud-Ouest du bénin »,
Europeanscientific journal, edition vol.13, No.3, 293-305.
Myerson R., (2011), « Construction de l'Etat,
leadership et démocratie locale », Revue française
d'économie 2 (Volume XXVI), 3-21.
Nishikant and Priyanka, (2018), «Migration, diaspora and
development: impressions from India», Journal of Enterprising
communities: People and places in the Global Economy, P. 11.
Nkwana H. M., (2012), «Leadership development for
developmental local government: Challenges and prospects», School of
Public Management and Administration University of Pretoria Pretoria South
Africa, African Journal of Public Affairs, Volume 5.
OECD, (2015), «Local Economic Leadership», LEED,
P.112.
Ozor N., and Nwankwo N, (2008), «The role of local
leaders in community development programmes in Ideato local government area of
Imo State: implication for extenssion policy», Journal of Agriculture
Extension, Department of Agricultural Extension, University of Nigeria,
63-75.
Paarlberg L.E. and Yoshioka T., (2016), «The impact of
local economic structure on community philanthropy», Public
administration Review, 76(2). 340-350. Doi: 10.1111/puar.12442.
Polyzouet, E., Jones, N., Evangelinos, K. I. and
Halvadakis, C. P., (2011), «Willingness to pay for drinking water
quality improvement and the influence of social capital». The
Journal of Socio Pretty, J. and S Economics 40: 74-80.
Public Health England, (2015), «Local leadership, new
approaches: how new ways of working are helping to improve the health of local
communities», PHE Publication: 2014712, P. 20.
Republic of South Africa, (1998), «White Paper on Local
Government, Pretoria: Government Printers».
Rodriguez-Pose, A and Tijmstra, S A.R, (2007), «Local
economic development in sub-Saharan Africa». Environment and Planning
C: Government and Policy, 25: 16-36.
Romeo L. G., (2013), «Decentralizing for development: The
developmental potential of local autonomy and the limits of politics-driven
decentralization reforms», Draft not for quotation, P. 1-23.
Saika S. B., (2010), «Motivation of Remittances and the
Potential for Diaspora Philanthropy: Empirical Studies of Rural Bangladesh, and
the US-Bangladeshi Diaspora». Undergraduate Honors Theses Paper 733,
1-132.
https://scholarworks.wm.edu/honorstheses/733
12.10.2020
Salomone, S. (2009). «Remittances.Overview of the
Existing Literature», Tor Vergata University.
Schlachter, Coleman and Anway, (2013), «Fiscal policy and
governance committee: Key Challenges and Strategies for Local Government»,
University of Pittsburgh, institute of Politics, 710 Alumni Hall 4227,
Fifth Avenue Pittsburgh, PA 15260, P.33.
Sheffer G., 1986, «A new field of study: modern diasporas
in international politics», in Gabriel Sheffer, (ed.), Modern Diasporas in
International Politics, London: Croom Helm, 1-15.
Smith S. M., 2010, «What is leadership?"
Sopchokchai O., (1996), «People's participation in
community Development», TDRI Quarterly review, vol.11, N° 3.
19-25.
Stark, O. and Levhari D., (1982), «On Migration and Risk
in LDCs». Economic Development and Cultural Change, 31,
191-196.
Swinburn, G. and Yatta, F., (2006), «Furthering the local
economic development agenda in Africa». Draft discussion paper presented
by the Municipal Development Partnership at Africities Congress. September,
Nairobi.
Targa-AIDE and Collectif et Modernité, (2015),
« Le Budget Participatif : des expériences à
l'international à sa mise en oeuvre au Maroc Partie I :
Définition du concept et revue des expériences »,
BritisEmbassy, Rabat. 1-49.
Trautman, S. Z., (2013), «From Zaire to the DRC: A case
study of State failure», Graduate theses and dissertation; unpublished.
Uddin N., (2019), «Empowering through participation in
local governance: the case of Union Parishad in Bangladesh», Public
Administration and Policy, vol. 22 N°. 1, PP. 40-54. DOI
10.1108/PAP-10-2018-002.
UNDP, (2006), «Leadership Development: Leading
transformations at the local level, a UNDP capacity development resource»,
conference paper, Working draft, P. 37.
UNDP, (2013), « fiche sur la gouvernance et la
décentralisation », libre papier, P. 4.
UNDP, (2015), «Decentralization and human development:
accelerating socio-economic transformation and sustaining accountable
governance», Rwanda 2014 National human Development report. P. 196.
UN-HABITAT, (2010). «Challenges of municipal finance in
Africa: with special rfere,ce to Gaborone City, Botswana», United Nations
Human Settlements Programme.
Varian, Hal R. (1992), Microeconomic Analysis, Vol. 3. New
York: W.W. Norton.
Vassilis and Kostas, (2010), «The application of the
contingent valuation method in estimating the climate change mitigation and
adaptation policies in Greece», An expert-based approach, Env Pol
Sustain, 12:807-824 DOI 10.1007/s10668-009-9225-0
Wall M. and Luther V, (2015), «Eight challenges facing
community leaders», Heartland Center for Leadership Development. 1-14.
World Bank and CRES, (2009), « Enquête
migration et transferts des fonds au Sénégal », P.
59.
Zhang A, (1996), «Economic Growth and Human Development
in China», Occasional Paper 28, 1-46.
Zongwe D. P.., (2019), «Democratic Republic of the
Congo», Online Compendium Autonomy Arrangements in the World. Available
on
www.world-autonomies.info
consulted on 12.01.2020.
CONTENT
IN MEMORIAM
II
DEDICATION
III
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
IV
ACRONYMS
V
ABSTRACT
VI
RESUME
VII
INTRODUCTION
1
CHAPTER ONE: LITERATURE REVIEW
6
I. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK
6
I.1. Local leadership empowerment
6
I.2. Chieftaincy
8
II.THEORIES
9
II.1. Local government in Democratic Republic of
the Congo
10
II.2. Empowering local leadership
12
III. HYPOTHESES BUILDING ON THE RESEARCH TOPIC
18
CHAPTER TWO: METHODOLOGY
25
I. DEFINITION OF THE POPULATION
25
II. SAMPLING TECHNIQUE AND DATA COLLECTION
25
II.1.The qualitative technique
25
II.2. The snowball technique
26
II.3. The questionnaire
26
II.4. Measuring variables
27
III. MODEL SPECIFICATION OF WILLINGNESS TO PAY
30
IV. DATA PROCESSING TECHNIQUE
32
CHAPTER THREE: RESULT PRESENTING AND
INTERPRETATION
33
I. GENERAL FEATURES OF NOTABLES
33
II. RELATED ECONOMETRIC ESTIMATE OF THE MODEL
37
II.2. Determinants of WTP towards Ngweshe local
leaders
37
II.3. Discussion and social implication of
findings
40
CONCLUSION
44
REFERENCES
45
CONTENT
53
APPENDIX
54
APPENDIX
Appendix 1: FACTOR ANALYSIS ON HOUSEHOLD ASSETS
KMO and Bartlett's Test
|
Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin Measure of Sampling Adequacy.
|
,857
|
Bartlett's Test of Sphericity
|
Approx. Chi-Square
|
3709,154
|
Df
|
231
|
Sig.
|
,000
|
Communalities
|
|
Initial
|
Extraction
|
Num_house
|
1,000
|
,777
|
Num_bed
|
1,000
|
,868
|
Num_cupboard
|
1,000
|
,821
|
Num_armchair
|
1,000
|
,758
|
Num_table
|
1,000
|
,880
|
Num_vehicle
|
1,000
|
,673
|
Num_motorb
|
1,000
|
,671
|
Num_computer
|
1,000
|
,783
|
Num_televis
|
1,000
|
,902
|
Num_radio
|
1,000
|
,464
|
Num_teleph
|
1,000
|
,522
|
Num_generat
|
1,000
|
,686
|
Num_freezer
|
1,000
|
,926
|
Num_Iron
|
1,000
|
,863
|
Num_cooker
|
1,000
|
,854
|
Num_solarpan
|
1,000
|
,801
|
Num_clipper
|
1,000
|
,704
|
Num_washbasi
|
1,000
|
,592
|
Num_wardrobe
|
1,000
|
,644
|
Num_sewingma
|
1,000
|
,481
|
Num_parcel
|
1,000
|
,425
|
Num_cow
|
1,000
|
,690
|
|
Appendix 2 : CORRELATION MATRIX OF VARIABLES
Appendsix 3: OUTCOME OF THE QUALITATIVE SURVEY
Working on "willingness to pay of the notability for local
leadership empowerment in Ngweshe", seven questions have been asked to 25
considered notables around Bukavu town. These questions mainly aimed at
assessing three features viewed to identify local leaders, their work, and
their supporters. Those questions are enumerated below:
1. What do you think about local leadership in Ngweshe
2. Who are those leaders?
3. What do you think about their work?
4. Do they contribute to local development?
5. How do you hope to help them?
6. Who are supposed to support them?
7. Do you think that groups of mutualities can help them?
· If yes, how much can you annually contribute when
supporting a developmental project?
· If not, what is the reason that causes people not to
contribute?
Results
1. Answering the first question regarding notables' thought
about local leadership in the chiefdom, it is observable that these notables
don't yet trust in local leadership. The truth is that they have supported that
local leaders have surrendered their mission and live today in town rather than
remaining near rural folks. Thus, a respondent has supposed that leadership
doesn't exist in Ngweshe. The chiefdom is ruled throughout "power of attorney"
held by some individuals living in the countryside. Another aspect noticed by
one of respondents was that local chieftaincy was influential in the society
through soil ownership. But currently their power and influence are facing
resistance of a new generation of wealth owners. There is in other ways a kind
of transfers of leadership from traditional chieftaince to current means
holders.
2. Notables mainly consider as local leaders in their native
chiefdom, all those people belonging to traditional and cultural chieftaincy:
the Mwami (King and chief of the chiefdom), chiefs of groupings, of Localities;
and many other kinds of individuals who exercise a certain influence on rural
lives.They thus are religious leaders, leader of schools, hospitals, and
influential economic agents.
3. While they are opportunists as deems one respondent, all
respondents have supported that their role is guiding, orienting, working with
the population, being its reporter, bear difficulties in interest of their
population. They have as well in their charge to be justice promoters and
regulate disputes in the community. They should be objective by avoiding
mismanaging or abandon to realize what folks wait from them. Notwithstanding,
it is recognized that retro-cession is allowed to entities even though they
aren't altogether delivered. That is, the Mwami uses that amount without any
control. What can lose trust of notables into local leadership in the chiefdom.
Respondents have suggested tooling the local civil society so as governance
takes another take-off within local leaders.
4. As for their contribution to developing the Ngweshe
chiefdom, respondents diverge on leaders' intention and orientation. In fact
some notables have asseverated that local leaders do not work in interest of
folks while others assume that some of rural leaders perfectly fulfill their
work in their entities. However, they notice that the mainstream of local
leaders is not educated and consequently have some limits which prevent them
from introducing new improving policies and actions. In a nutshell, only a few
leaders are implicated in development action.
5. Their answer on the way to help local leaders is mostly
building their capacity, being close to them, help to understand the current
context and the global evolution of the region. Also, encourage stakeholders
(local leaders, local folks,etc.) to adopt participatory budget in the entity
so as they boost development schemes. Here, responsible of the civil society
mainly and the whole population have in their attribution to monitor their
actions. However, an individual has said that there is no way to help local
leaders because they even embezzle remitted retrocession. What shows that all
individual may not will to pay as a result of trust lose.
6. Several interventions at different level are requisite.
Primarily, local leaders shall count on their own population through levy
collection even though rural citizens are pauperized, State leaders at national
and provincial level, NGO, Universities,natives living outer the chiefdom,
organizations, etc. Inquired individuals have estimated the variability of
their support amount to local leaders regarding each scheme taking into account
its collective utility and budget needed.
7.Despite that an individual assumed that he cannot contribute
for empowering local leadership, noticing their behavior of living in town
rather than being in rural area and the fact that they embezzle amounts allowed
to rural development, others have asserted to pay between 50 and USD 1500.
Appendix: SURVEY QUESTIONNAIRE
My name is Romeo MUNGUAKONKWA, a student in license in rural
economics at the Catholic university of Bukavu. This survey is realized with
the purpose to fulfill our graduate paper carried on Willingness to
pay of the notability for local leadership empowerment in
Ngweshe. It aims to assess the level to which the rural
notability dwelling in Bukavu would be ready to fund their local leaders (rural
authorities) in their home chiefdom so as developmental projects can be
undertaken under them. Given that we provide you the maximum confidentiality on
data you're going to provide us, we beg you to provide your uninfluenced
answers as an inherent contribution to this research.
N° questionnaire
|
Date
|
Grouping of origin
|
Starting time
|
Ending time
|
|
|
|
|
|
Module 1. CARACTERISTIQUES SOCIOECONOMIQUES DU NOTABLE
ET DE SON MENAGE
1. Age
|
|
2. household size
|
|
3. Sex 0. Male 1. Female
|
|
4. Marital status:
1. Single [ ] 2. Married [ ] 3. Divorced [
] 4. widow [ ]
|
|
5. Level of study
1. none 2. Primary 3. Secondary 4. Academic
|
|
6. Religion
1. Catholic 2. Protestant 3. Muslim 4. Kimbanguist 5.
Other
|
|
7. From when do you live in Bukavu ?
|
|
8. what is your status in the household?
1. head 2. Spouse 3. Other
|
|
8. Do you belong to a mutual or an association? 1. Yes
2. No
|
|
9. If yes, which duration has it taken?
|
|
10. Do you permanently access to water in your household?
1. Yes 2. No
|
|
12. Do you permanently access to electricity in your
household? 1. Yes 2. No
|
|
13. Accommodation
1. Durable 2. Semi-durable 3. Shelf 4. Mire 5. Other
|
|
14. Dwelling place
1. Ibanda. 2. Kadutu. 3. Bagira
|
|
15. If you are married, what is your spouse's educational
level
1. none 2. Primary 3. Secondary 4. Academic
|
|
16. what is his/her profession?
1. Unemployed 2. Salaried 3. Mercantile 4. Farmer 5. craft
6. Other
|
|
Income
|
Resource approach
|
1.
|
What is your monthly income?
|
........................
|
2.
|
What is your spouse's monthly income
|
........................
|
3.
|
If there are other active members in your household, what is
their monthly income?
|
........................
|
Expenditure approach
|
What are your household's alimentary and no alimentary
expenditure?
|
Monthly expenditure in USD
1. Food +beverage .................
2. Transport .................
3. Communication .................
4. Cloths and footwear.................
5. Cosmetic products and bath soap .................
6. washing soap .................
7. Petrol, gas and other energetic springs
.................
8. Water and electricity .................
9. Leisure .................
10. Other monthly expenditure .................
|
Yearly expenditure in USD
11. Fee of medicine and health .................
12. Schooling .................
13. Rent on house .................
14. Credit repayment .................
15. Social expenses .................
16. Journey .................
17. Other yearly expenditure .................
|
Householdassets
Do you possess
|
How many
|
Do you possess
|
How many?
|
House
|
|___|
|
Generating set
|
|___|
|
Bed
|
|___|
|
Freezer
|
|___|
|
Cupboard
|
|___|
|
Iron
|
|___|
|
Armchair
|
|___|
|
Camping stove/ cooker
|
|___|
|
Table
|
|___|
|
Solar panel
|
|___|
|
Vehicle
|
|___|
|
Clipper
|
|___|
|
Motorbike
|
|___|
|
Washbasin
|
|___|
|
Computer
|
|___|
|
Wardrobe
|
|___|
|
Television
|
|___|
|
Sewing machine
|
|___|
|
Radio
|
|___|
|
Parcel
|
|___|
|
Telephone
|
|___|
|
Cow
|
|___|
|
General information on the respondent's
activity
|
1. In which sector is located your primary activity?
1. Agriculture, breeding and fishing [ ] 2. Manufacture
[ ] 3. General trade [ ] 4.Craft [ ]
5. Public sector [ ] 6. NGO [ ] 7. Other [ ]
|
2. What is your status in that sector?
1. Salaried [ ] 2. Independent [ ] 3. Employer [
]
|
3. Is the organization in which you work recorded in formal
sector?
0. No [ ] 1. Yes [ ]
|
4. How many years have you realized in that
sector (activity)?.................
|
5. In how many activities or sectors are you
involved ?.................
|
6. In which sector is located your secondary activity?
1. Agriculture, breeding and fishing [ ] 2. Manufacture
[ ] 3. General Trade [ ] 4.Craft [ ]
5. Public sector [ ] 6. NGO [ ] 7. Other [ ]
|
7. What is your status in that sector?
1. Salaried [ ] 2. Independent [ ] 3. Employer [
]
|
8. Is the organization in which you work recorded in formal
sector?
0. No [ ] 1. Yes [ ]
|
9. How many years have you realized in that sector (activity)?
.................
|
10. For how much do you believe your monthly income from
your primary activity? .................
|
11. For how much do you believe your monthly income from your
secondary activity ?.................
|
Educationalburden
|
1.
|
How many members of your household are schooled?
|
Primary school
|
.........
|
Secondary school
|
.........
|
Primary school
|
.........
|
2.
|
How much do you yearly pay for the education of your
children ?
|
Primary school
|
.........
|
Secondary school
|
.........
|
College/ University
|
.........
|
3.
|
How much do you allocate to educating outer persons ?
|
Primary school
|
.........
|
Secondary school
|
.........
|
College/ University
|
.........
|
4.
|
If school fees fade, will you your contribution towards local
leadership ?
|
1. Yes 2. No
|
|___|
|
5.
|
Do you expect that ulterior returns to schooling of those
you're bearing will improve your contribution?
|
1. Yes 2. No
|
|___|
|
Module 2. WILLINGNESS TO PAY
In the spirit of this work is the intervention of two kinds of
partners, notably local leaders who are ruling at
several level of the rural society and notables
emerging from Ngweshe and leaving in Bukavu. Given that, local leaders are
performers as wants decentralization. But they face a decrease of retrocession.
Regardful to developing your native chiefdom, you are asked this question:
Are you predisposed to improve local leadership for
Ngweshedevelopment ? Yes |___| No |___|
|
Willing to improve local leadership
|
|
Yes
|
No
|
1. You trust local leaders in Ngweshe
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
2. You participate to local development in Ngweshe
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
3. Local development of Ngweshe is your priority
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
4. Local leaders need trainings in management and local
governance
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
5. Development of Ngweshe must be committed by rural local
leaders
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
6. Rural leaders are near folks
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
7. These leaders work for folks' welfare in Ngweshe
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
8. There must be a joint-committee (Notables and local
leaders) to monitor social project fulfillment in Ngweshe
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
9. Your motivation to participate is related to self interest
in Ngweshe rather than collectively born development
|
|___|
|
|___|
|
Social capital
|
1. Is your participation to local leadership reinforcement
tied to your friends' participation? 0. No 1. Yes
|
|
2. If yes, how many participate? .................
|
3. How many people of great notoriety encourage you
participating to developing local leadership?...............
|
4. How many active fellow workers encourage you to contribute?
.................
|
5. Is there any organization or group where members are
encouraged to disburse towards local leadership empowerment in Ngweshe?
0. No 1. Yes
|
|
6. If yes, how many are they?
.................
|
7. Do your work managers having influence on your source of
income push you to pool?
0. No 1. Yes
|
|
8. If Yes, why do you accept to pool? 1. Love of chiefdom 2
To persuade them 3. By fear to be fired. 4. Other 5. None
..................................................
|
Willingness to pay
|
Now, some are presented some imaginary scenarios on which your
opinion is needed: local leaders' role being assuring social well-being of
communities and thus local development. Got it the lower penetration of
retrocession funds for developing the
EntitésTerritorialeDécentralisées, among which
Ngweshe chiefdom, the developmental process would decelerate. As well, loses
and challenges would surprisingly raise. Being recognized as notable of the
area, your contribution would help to fill the gap. Thus, you are presented the
following questions to withdraw your strain for financially tooling local
leaders in Ngweshe.
|
1. In order to reinforce local leadership,
are you ready to yearly pay in USD and in accordance to each project an amount
the following amount: 250/ 1000/1500/2000
Yes |___| No |___|
Ø If yes on question (1), are you
ready to pay above the following amounts in USD 350/1100/1700/2800
Yes |___| No |___|
Ø If no on question (1), are you ready
to pay above the following amounts 150/600/900/1200?
Yes |___| No |___|
Ø If you don't admit any bid, then, what is the amount
you would willingly give? .........................................
|
Execution priority of crowdfunded
projects
Seen that your contributions will go through local leaders,
you are just now presented several developmental projects asking you to give
your point of view on their priority. There is no bad
answer; it all depends on your own perception of the priority on their
performance.
|
Here's the meaning of the number suggested by the scale
1= Very low priority 2= low priority 3= neutral
4= Priority 5= very high priority
|
Current level of priority given to the project fields
|
In the future perspective, please express your
wish for priority execution on the projects
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
1. Project aiming at increasing the production of
vegetables
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
2. Project aiming at increasing the production of legumins
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
3. Project aiming at increasing the production of cereals
(Maize, Sorghum, Rice,...)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
4. Project aiming at increase the production of roots
(cassava, Potato, yam, taro,...)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
5. Project aiming at increasing animal production (ovine,
porcine, goat, bovine,...) and milk
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
6. Project to make sustainable and productive banana
cultivation
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
7. Project for sustainability of peace in the chiefdom
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
8. Project for chiefdom electrification
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
9. Water supply project for the needy villages
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
10. For a hospital infrastructure construction Project
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
11. For a comfortable six class construction project
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
12. For a project to build a solar power plant per general
hospital in Ngweshe
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
13. Project to install a flour mill for the production of
flour in Ngweshe
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Motivation to participate to the local leadership
empowerment process
|
Here are some propositions relative to facts that
would influence the amount you can be disposed to give for leadership
empowerment in Ngweshe. For each one of them, please express your level of
agreement on the following scale: 1. Very much agree 2. Alright
3. Neutral 4. Disagree 5. Not altogether agree.
There is no bad answer; it all depends on your own encouraging
reasons of participation.
|
Motivation
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
1. I will be ready to participate to collectively financing
local leaders for being a share of those who will have allowed development in
Ngweshe
|
|
|
|
|
|
2. I will be ready to participate to collectively financing
local leaders provided that they are transparent
|
|
|
|
|
|
3. I would like to participate to collectively financing local
leadership so as peace becomes sustainable in Ngweshe
|
|
|
|
|
|
4. I would give funds and my participatory share provided that
it goes through the planning of my ulterior investments in Ngweshe
|
|
|
|
|
|
5. I would like to participate provided that those who
embezzle funds come in question before the justice
|
|
|
|
|
|
6. I would like to participate to the process of crowdfunding
towards local leadership in order to rise crops production
|
|
|
|
|
|
7. My contribution to projects targeting development under
local leadership is mainly prompted by my political ambitions in the area
|
|
|
|
|
|
Starting Price
|
1.
|
Is there any set amount when contributing in your
organization?
|
1. Yes 2. No
|
2.
|
If yes, what is the monthly set amount?
|
..................
|
3.
|
If no, is it a good policy?
|
1. Yes 2. No
|
4.
|
What is the mean amount you would give after a year?
|
..................
|
Selected grouping for the project
|
1.
|
Do you wish projects undertaken to be first applied in your
home grouping?
|
1. Yes 2. No
|
|___|
|
2.
|
Suppose that you're the policy decider, will you implement the
most important projects in your home grouping rather than others of your
chiefdom?
|
1. Yes 2. No
|
|___|
|
3.
|
If yes (to question 2), what incites you to
pay such an attention to towards your home grouping?
|
1. Community tie
2. Your center of interest
|
|___|
|
We thank you very much for your availability to
contribute to this research fulfillment
* 1
http://vigilancerdc.afrikblog.com/archives/2008/03/15/8328226.html
https://scooprdc.net/2018/04/24/retrocession-aux-provinces-les-gouverneurs-a-kinshasa-pour-mendier-la-generosite-de-mova/
* 2
http://radar.oreilly.com/2012/07/mobile-participatory-budgeting-helps-raise-tax-revenues-in-congo.html
* 3
http://www.banquemondiale.org/fr/news/feature/2012/09/10/participatory-budgeting-an-experience-in-good-governance
* 4
https://fr.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Notable
* 5This table is altogether
referred from Englebert and Kasongo (2016) with the whole related legend
*
6https://www.carnetsdubusiness.com/Les-nouveaux-mecanismes-du-consentement-a-payer_a618.html
* 7Patrick ROBO (1995) deems the
existence of saturation since collected data and their analysis don't provide
any additional information in the under way research.
* 8They are recognized to
having introduced the use of dichotomous variables
* 9The variable Willingness to
pay is diveded into two colums: the lower and the higher value expressed to pay.
* 10 In DR Congo, life
expectancy was respectively 56.5 and 59.7 respectively for male and female in
2018.The information is published by Index Mundi on the web page published in
December 2019
www.indexmundi.com/democrqtic_republic_of_the_congo/life_expectancy_at_birth.html