Governance, Quality of Institutions and
Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence
from a Cross-National Analysis
Abdelkarim YAHYAOUI, Ouidade CHATTI & Nouri CHTOUROU
Governance, Quality of Institutions and Economic
Growth: Empirical Evidence from a Cross-National Analysis
Abdelkarim YAHYAOUI*
Ouidade CHATTI**
Nouri CHTOUROU*** February 2008
Abstract: This paper examines
the relationship between the quality of institutions and economic growth. The
first part will be devoted to the definition of the concept of governance and
its measurements. In the second part we will briefly review the literature on
the relation between governance and growth. Finally, we will carry out an
empirical investigation by using an endogenous model of growth, which deals
with the relation between governance and growth in 96 countries. Using a cross
section analysis, the estimation results prove that there is a strongly
significant relation between the institutional variables used in our work and
the income per capita.
Résumé: Ce papier examine le
lien entre la qualité des institutions et la croissance
économique. La première partie sera consacrée à la
définition du concept de gouvernance et à ses mesures. La
deuxième partie fera l'objet d'une revue de la littérature sur la
relation entre gouvernance et croissance. Enfin, dans la dernière
partie, on va effectuer une investigation empirique en utilisant un
modèle de croissance endogène, traitant de la relation entre
gouvernance et croissance dans 96 pays. Les résultats d'estimation avec
l'analyse en coupe transversale prouvent qu'il y a une relation fortement
significative entre les variables institutionnelles utilisées dans notre
travail et le revenu par tête.
Key words: Governance, Quality of
Institutions, Economic Growth, Cross-Section. Classification
JEL: O43, C2 1
* URED, Faculty of Economics and Management of Sfax 3029,
Tunisia :abdelkarim.yahyaoui@
fsegs.rnu.tn ** CEMAFI-URED, Faculty
of Right, Political Sciences, Economic and Management of Nice:
ouidade_chatti@yahoo.fr ***
URED, Faculty of Economics and Management of Sfax:
nouri.chtourou@fsegs.rnu.tn
1. Introduction
Since the beginning of the 1990is, the concept of
governance has gained a remarkable importance. It has currently become part of
the common vocabulary used by financial institutions and by in the
international development institutions as well (WB, IMF, and UNDP). It is based
primarily on the introduction of new reforms neither economic nor financial but
institutional, aiming essentially at the improvement of the State. In the same
time, we witness a renewed interest for the concept of institutions and in
particular for the question of their capability of supporting the growth. These
two concepts, governance and institutions, have become truly operational and
have been actually introduced into the studying process of developing countries
only recently, following the first evaluations of the Structural Adjustment
Programs (SAP). Ever since, they have become dominant concepts in the
management of public affairs. So, the role of the governance and institutional
quality in the determination of long run economic performances is a subject
which has preoccupied the economists of development and economic growth for
many years.
On the theoretical level, a very great agreement has already
been achieved toward recognizing the benefits of good governance when it comes
to developing countries and the fact that good public institutions lead to a
better governance. So the question of governance joins that of the institutions
and analyzing the first one necessarily requires studying the question of the
institutions capacity of supporting the growth.
After a decade of hard work to figure out the role of the
governance in the development, several basic questions persist: what does the
concept of governance consist of? How to measure it? What is the link between
governance and growth?
Our principal objective in this work is to try to contribute
to a more precise knowledge of this concept of governance and measurement in
order to evaluate it, as well as of the links between the governance and the
economic growth both on the theoretical level and on the empirical one.
Our article is organized in the following way. The first
section will be devoted to the definition of the concept of governance and its
measurements. In the second section we will briefly review the literature about
the relation between governance and growth. Finally the last section consists
of an empirical investigation through an endogenous growth model explaining the
relation between governance and growth in 96 countries.
2. Governance: concepts and measurements
The term of governance appears in the French language at the
beginning of the 1 3th century as equivalent to the term of
government1. Since the beginning of the 1990is, the
governance has been a fashionable word. It is a term carrying several meanings
and in constant evolution. This word has more than one meaning: first it refers
to companies' governance or "corporate governance", the second to the global
governance, the third to the national governance and finally the fourth to the
local governance. It is the national governance which specifically interests us
in this work.
The concept of national governance and the expression
«good governance" appear at the beginning of the 1 990s, in the
vocabulary used by the vast international institutions and more particularly
the World Bank In 1992, the latter defines governance as the way in which the
power is exerted to manage the economic and social resources of a country. For
the World Bank good governance is a sign of a healthily managed development
(World Bank, 1992).Today this concept has been adopted by development agencies
and the various international or regional organizations. Each has developed its
own definition of governance.
In the continuation of our work, we mean by governance «
the traditions and institutions by which authority in a country is exercised.
This includes (1) the process by which governments are selected, monitored and
replaced, (2) the capability of the government to effectively formulate and
implement sound policies, and (3) the respect of citizens and the state for the
institutions that govern economic and social interactions among them"
(Kaufmann, Kraay & Zoido-Lobaton 1999; p. 1). They then construct six
1 The Robert, Historic Dictionary of the French
Language, Paris 1992, opt quoted Campbell.
aggregate indicators corresponding to six basic governance
concepts: voice and accountability, political instability and
violence, government effectiveness, regulatory burden, rule of law, and graft.
We preferred this definition to the one provided by the World Bank because it
takes into account the nature of the political régimes.
In spite of its importance, the governance remains an evasive
concept without any clear consensus regarding the subject of what it consists
of. The question of the governance takes us then to that of the institutions
and the study of the first one must necessarily pass by the study of the
question of the ability of institutions to support the growth. Indeed, no clear
distinction can be made between the concept of governance and institutional
factor. Institutions generally correspond to a broader concept which includes
the formal and informal constraints, rules and laws which are associated not
only with the state's functioning but also with that of the private
entities.2
The recent interest for governance and its economic
consequences accompanied the need to evaluate its various dimensions. Today
measuring the governance is as important well from the point of view of the
national policy, as it is from of the international economic relations point of
view or from the point of view of research in economic and political
sciences.
There are different types of indicators: data resulting from
investigations, those from experts' surveys and aggregate indicators. Data
resulting from investigations are indicators related to the national averages
of the answers to the questions raised in connection with the governance. An
example of these investigations is World Business Environment Survey 2000
(WBES). We also point out to the data resulting from experts' surveys
which consist of classifications generally produced by rating agencies,
nongovernmental organizations (NGO) or international organizations. They are
made in a consensual way starting from the judgments of individuals who know
relatively well the reality of the country which they evaluate. A private
agency of risk notation, The Political Risk Service Group (PRSG), produces
database entitled research data set. It contains
02 World Economic Survey, chapter V: « Diverging
Growth and Development », Development Policy and Analysis Division.
annual evaluations on the quality of governance over the
period 1984-2006.Those are built starting from monthly data of the
International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), one of the products of the PRSG.
This database offers measurements of the various aspects of
governance like political stability, ethnic tensions or internal conflicts. In
this article, we are going to use five indicators of this database: corruption
(COR), Law and Order (LO), democratic accountability (DA), bureaucratic quality
(BQ) and Government Stability (GS). The first three indicators go from 0 to 6,
the fourth from 0 to 4 and the last one goes from 0 to 12. In all the cases,
the highest values reflect better notes, i.e. less corruption, a more effective
legal system, a better democratic accountability, a better bureaucracy, and low
government instability.
The corruption indicator measures the abuse of the public
power when it is exercised for private gain. Low scores indicate that senior
officials are very corruptible and that corruption is generalized in the whole
administration. The quality indicator of the legal system reflects the power
and the impartiality of the legal system as well as the observance of the law.
The indicator of the democratic accountability reflects the capacity of the
government to install a democratic society. The indicator of the bureaucracy
quality measures at the same time the independence and the autonomy of the
administration with respect to the political power and the changesb of the
executive power, as well as the incentives which the civil servants have to
work through mechanisms of recruitment and promotion. Lastly, the indicator of
political stability reflects political violence and instability in the
country.
Composite indicators are generally those of the World Bank and
Transparency International. Since 1995, Transparency
International has annually produced a Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI).
The World Bank provides a database named World Wide Governance Research
Indicators, also called by the name of its authors Kauffman, Kraay and
Mastruzzi (2006). This database consists of six indicators of governance,
obtained for 213 autonomous countries and territories, at six different dates:
1996, 1998, 2000, 2002, 2004 and 2005. The Indicators diversity is explained by
the complexity and
multidimensional character of the governance. These six
indicators which will be used in our work are the following:
1- Control of Corruption (CC) - measuring the extent
to which public power is exercised for private gain, including both petty and
grand forms of corruption, as well as "capture" of the state by elites and
private interest;
2- Government Effectiveness (GE) - measuring the
quality of public services, the quality of the civil service and the degree of
its independence from political pressures, the quality of policy formulation
and implementation, and the credibility of the government's commitment to such
policies;
3- Political Stability (PS) - measuring perceptions
of the likelihood that the government will be destabilized or overthrown by
unconstitutional or violent means, including domestic violence and
terrorism;
4- Rule of Law (RL) - measuring the extent to which
agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, and in particular
the quality of contract enforcement, the police, and the courts, as well as the
likelihood of crime and violence;
5- Regulatory Quality (RQ) - measuring the ability
of the government to formulate and implement sound policies and regulations
that permit and promote private sector development;
6- Voice and Accountability (VA) - measuring the
extent to which a country's citizens are able to participate in selecting their
government, as well as freedom of expression, freedom of association, and a
free media.
These indicators are qualified as composites or aggregate ones
because they are elaborate starting from the results of investigations and
rating of experts relating to corruption and other aspects of governance.
3. Governance and economic growth: literature review
Many authors recognize the benefits of good governance when it
comes to the developing countries. According to these authors, good public
institutions allow good governance. So the question of the governance is linked
to that of the institutions and the
analysis of the first one necessarily passes by the study of
the question of the capacity of institutions to support the
growth.3
In this direction, a wide literature has already been built to
show the importance of institutions in the determination of long run economic
performances on the theoretical level and on the empirical level as well. On
the one hand, we find the theoretical work of the New Institutional Economics
(NIE) and of the new endogenous theory of growth, and on the other hand, we
find the empirical work in the forms of cross-section study of the growth
through the countries which seek to establish a relation between governance or
quality of institutions and economic growth.
On the theoretical level, the NIE having North as file leader,
shows that effective institutions can make the difference in the success of the
market reforms and even affirms that institutions constitute one of the
determining factors of the economic growth in the long run. North (1990)
defines the institutions as "the rules of the game" which shape the human
behaviors in a company. The institutions have a very significant role in the
company because they determine the fundamental structure of the human
interactions, whether they are political, social or economic.
A State equipped with a legal system and effective property
right is a State which creates a favorable environment to capital accumulation
and growth. While defective institutions create a market for nonproductive
activities such as rent seeking, corruption, and also generate high transaction
costs and of course handicapping economic inefficiencies. So the institutions
act in a direct way on the intensity of the investment and thereby on the
growth. The impacts of the quality of institutions on long run economic
performances are spread by the means of the cost-cutting of transactions,
limitation of the risks and disappearance of rigidities which deteriorate the
markets (Chtourou 2004).
We also point out to the work of the theory of endogenous
growth. Following the insufficiencies of exogenous growth models to explain a
stable growth in the situation of equilibrium, new models of growth emerged
specifying the necessary conditions that
3 Throughout this work, the concepts of gouvernance
and institutions will be employed to say the same thing.
guarantee a long run growth, known as endogenous
growth. The new theory of endogenous growth was developed by several
economists such as Lucas (1988), Romer (1986), McKinnon and Shaw (1973), Barro
(1989), Roubini and Salt-I-Martin (1995)... etc. these works took a better
advantage of the data resulting from the economic sphere to try to justify the
variations of growth between countries.
However, the limits of the estimates that have been carried
out, and in particular the need for adding regional dummies within the models
to manage to explain the variance of observations, suggested the incompleteness
of models which are being limited to the economic indicators to explain the
behavior of the growth.
This reflexion encouraged the economists to turn out to the
institutional variables to try to find a justification for the production gap
that exists between countries and unexplained by the only economic data.
Several political and institutional factors were then presented: the democracy
according to Barro (1996), the respect of the property rights according to
Clague, Keefer and Olson (1996), political instability according to Alesina and
Perotti (1994). Rodrik (1999) supports the idea that good governance would be a
necessary condition for market economies success. Hall and Jones (1999) show
that the differences observed in the intensity of physical capital and in the
education level realized, explain only a small fraction in the differences
noted in the levels of output per worker through countries. So they show that
the differences in the social infrastructure (institutions and governmental
policy) through nations account for the differences noted in capital
accumulation, the level of education carried out and the productivity, which
explain the disparity in the level of income and development of countries.
On the empirical level, one finds a wide empirical literature
enhancing the importance of the governance and the institutions as a
determining factor of growth and development. This literature appears in the
form of cross section studies of the growth across countries which seek to
establish a positive correlation between the quality of governance and the
growth.
The income per capita or the growth rate is regressed on
several governance indicators: narrow indicators such as civil freedoms, rules
of laws, property rights, political stability, and global indicators of
governance. Other variables are used in these regressions however they are not
related to the governance like geographical and historical variables.
Kormendi and Meguire (1985), Scully (1988), Grier and Tullock
(1989), Barro (1996) and Helliwell (1994) and Isham, Kaufman and Pritchett
(1997) all confirm the existence of a positive correlation between the civil
freedoms indicator as an institutional framework measures, and the economic
growth for the majority of countries taken in their sample.
Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2004) showed that the
variation of growth between rich and poor countries is mainly due to the
difference in the guarantee of the property rights in these countries. Rodrik,
Subramanian and Trebbi (2002), in their study, confirm the idea according to
which the guarantee of property rights accelerates the growth.
Barro (1991) and Londregan & Poole (1992) state that
political instability and violence generate a weak growth. Alesina and Perotti
(1996) and Svensson (1998) note a negative effect of political instability on
the investment.
we also find the studies of Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi
(2004) who use an indicator of the rules and laws to show that good governance
exerts a positive effect on growth. They find a strong and positive correlation
between this indicator and the income level.
Mauro (1995) tests three indices made by the International
Business (IB): index of corruption, index of bureaucratic quality and the index
of political stability. He finds that these three indicators are related
positively and significantly to the growth and the investment. Knack and Keefer
(1995) use two indicators collected in the ICRG and the BERI. They create two
indices, the first for measuring the security of contracts and the second for
the property rights, and they find an expected positive effect of these
indicators on the growth. Easterly and Levine (2002) use the
global index of governance of Kaufmann, Kray, Zoido-Lobation (2002) to show
that the governance affects the growth positively and significantly.
We notice that the empirical literature, throughout narrow
indicators of the governance as well as through the global indicators, actually
shows that the governance has a strong influence on the levels of incomes.
These studies confirm a strong, positive and significant correlation between
good governance and economic performances.
This is why we are going to try, in the following paragraphs,
to validate this report by an empirical analysis using the cross-sections
method.
4. Empirical analysis of the relation between governance
and economic growth
On this level of analysis we seek to study the impact of
various measurements of the governance on the long run global economic
performances in 96 countries. Basing our study on the model of growth of Mankiw
& al. (1992), Knight & al. (1993) and Ghra
& Hadjmichael (1996) [quoted by Demetriades and Law, 2006,
p. 5)]. Our starting point is the following Cobb-Douglas production
function:
Y t K t H t ( A t
L t )
á â - á -
â
(1)
1
=
Where Y is real output, K is the stock of
physical capital, H is the stock of human capital, L is the
raw labour, A is a labour-augmenting factor reflecting the level of
technology and efficiency in the economy and the subscript t indicates
time.
It is assumed that á + â < 1, i.e.
decreasing returns to all capital (physical capital and human capital). Raw
labour and labour-augmenting technology are assumed to grow according to the
following functions:
L t = L 0e nt
(2)
t A 0
A = e
where n is the exogenous rate of growth of the labour
force, g is the exogenous rate of technological progress, P
is a vector of financial development, institutions and other factors that
can affect the level of technology and efficiency in the economy, and è
is a vector of coefficients related to these variables.
In this model, the variable A depends on the
exogenous technological improvements, the degree of commercial opening and the
level of other variables. It is obvious that A in our study
differs from that employed by Mankiw and al. (1992). This modification is
particularly appropriate to the empirical validation of the relations between
Institutions quality and economic growth. The technological improvements are
encouraged by effective institutions (North 1990) and by healthy institutional
environment (World Bank).
In equilibrium condition, the output per capita increases at a
constant rate G (the exogenous component of the growth rate of the variable
reflecting the level of technology and efficiency of an economy). These results
can be obtained directly from the definition of output per effective worker
(Average Labour Productivity):
Y = t
AL
t t
;
( ) á ( )â
k . h
t t
Y
t A . k . h
= ( ) á (
)â (4)4
t t t
t
L
With
|
? ?
* t
=
Y
y ?
t L
?
? t ?
|
*
|
As we apply the logarithm on the two sides for the equation (4)
and to simplify calculation we eliminate the time index, we have then:
á â
- -
|
Y L
|
t A .
= t
t
|
( ) á ( )â
k . h
t t
|
1
Y K H A L
á â ( )
4 t t t t t
=
t
AL
t
( ) á á â â
1 - + - +
A L
t t
á â á â
1 - -
Y ? K ? ? H ? ? A L ?
; t t t t t
= ? ? . ? ? . ? ?
= ( ) á ( )â
k . h
t t
ALA L
t t ? t t ?A L A L
? t t ? ? t t ?
Y ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ä)
á â á â
+
*
Ln( = + + +
) Ln A g.t .P
è - + + (5)5
L 1 - -
á â 1 - -
á â 1 - -
á â
0 k h
Ln s + Ln s Ln n g
The equation (5) determines the output per capita in the
equilibrium state; also in this equation the vector p gather
the institutional variables which will be defined in the fallowing
paragraph.
Because of a data limitation, one can suppose in this study
that sh and g.t do not change through time (Demetriades and Law
(2006)), whereas sk and n vary Indeed, Ln (A 0), g.t and
sh can be gathered in a constant á0 in the equation (6).
Therefore, output per capita (also called Average Labour Productivity) is given
by:
Y á ( ) ( ä
? á â
+ ?
Ln( *
) = + +
á è
0 . .P k
Ln s + -
? ? .Ln n g
+ + ) (6)
L 1 - -
á â ? 1 - -
á â ?
With P: the vector gathering institutional variables.
After simplification of the equation (6), we obtain an equation
of evaluation for the relation between the quality of institutions and output
per capita:
Lny 0 1 . INS 2 . Ink 3 . In n g
= + + + + +
á á á á ( ä )
(7)
With, y Gross domestic product per capita (GDP/capita); INS a
vector gathering the institutional variables, k is the stock of capital
investment or physical capital accumulation; n is the rate of labour force; g
is the rate of technology growth or technological progress and ä is the
rate of depreciation. g and ä are assumed to be constant
across countries and over time and their sum equals 0.05, following Mankiw
and al. (1992, p.413). á0, á1,
á2 and á3 are the parameters to be
estimated.
1 1
and
1 â â á â
? s . s
- - -
? 1
5 At equilibrium one has; k * ??
h
k
= ?? ä + +
g n
1 - á á
1
á â
- -
? s . s ?
h * ??
k
h
= ?? ä + +
g n
4.1. Econometric approach
The equation (7) is considered as the base for the empirical
models which will be estimated by the cross-section method:
For the econometric approach the equation (7) will be modified as
follows:
y= á0 + á' X+ î(8)
ii i
i = 1, 2, ..., 96
With, y is real GDP per capita in logarithm, á
0 constant, á' =
(á1,á2,á3)
a vector of dimension (3;1), X i = (X1 ,i ;X2 ,i ;X3 ,i ) vector of
explanatory variables, and îi innovations supposed to be independently
identical of null mean and variance ó î 2.
4.2. Presentation of the variables and their sources
As endogenous variable, one takes GDP/capita in logarithm
Ln(y).The basic and control variables are respectively, labour force
(n), the accumulation of physical capital in logarithm Ln(k) obtained by the
variable ``Gross fixed capital formation" in logarithm. The institutional
variables are obtained from two sources: Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2006)
and the ICRG (2007). The indicators of governance of Kaufmann selected are
defined in the first part of this work and are respectively; voice and
accountability, political stability, government effectiveness, regulatory
quality, rule of law, and control of corruption. We then held from ICRG, five
institutional variables which are: government stability (GS), corruption (COR),
laws and orders (LO), bureaucratic quality (BQ) and the Democratic
Accountability (DA).
5. Results of estimates
By using the cross-section method on 96 countries6 and
by making the average for each variable over the period 1996-2003, we obtain
the results presented in the tables below.
6 The choice of the 96 countries was made according to
the availability of the data.
For the first table, there is a regression in function with
the variables of bases only (Model 1 :M1). For the remainder of the
regressions, we integrate each time one of the six indicators of governance
from the data base of KAUFMANN7.
Table 1. Dependent variable. In y
(Governance Indicators. KA UFMANN)
|
M1
|
M2
|
M3
|
M4
|
M5
|
M6
|
M7
|
Cste
|
-4.280 (-3.400)
|
2.790 (2.023)
|
1.648 (1.237)
|
3.473 (2.788)
|
2.617 (2.253)
|
3.498 (2.902)
|
2.905 (2.491)
|
Ln(n+g+ä)
|
-2.047 (-4.088)
|
0.065 (0.134)
|
-0.142 (-0.289)
|
-0.400 (-0.986)
|
-0.373 (-0.93 1)
|
-0.305 (-0.76)
|
-0.340 (-0.855)
|
Lnk
|
0.324 (8.165)
|
0.260 (7.961)
|
0.291 (8.912)
|
0.171 (5.124)
|
0.208 (6.717)
|
0.184 (5.793)
|
0.205 (6.659)
|
KAUFMANN
|
VA
|
|
0.689 (7.444)
|
|
|
|
|
|
PS
|
|
|
0.633 (6.957)
|
|
|
|
|
GE
|
|
|
|
0.711 (9.171)
|
|
|
|
RQ
|
|
|
|
|
0.893 (9.429)
|
|
|
RL
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.725 (9.617)
|
|
CC
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.648 (9.603)
|
N. Obs
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
R2
|
0.597
|
0.748
|
0.736
|
0.789
|
0.795
|
0.799
|
0.799
|
7 For each indicator of gouvernance one makes the
average of the data available: 1/5 * (Value 96+ Value 98+ Value 2000+ Value
2002+ Value 2003).
For the second table and for each regression, we integrate each
time one of the five institutional variables8 selected by the
ICRG9.
Table 2. Dependent variable . In y
(Institutional Quality. ICR G)
|
M8
|
M9
|
M 10
|
M 11
|
M 12
|
Cste
Ln(n+g+ä)
Lnk
GS COR LO BQ DA
|
-5.338 (-3.557)
|
-1.521 (-1.334)
|
-2.110 (-1.660)
|
1.726 (1.476)
|
-1.873 (-1.42)
|
-2.085 (-4.172)
|
-0.850 (-1.850)
|
-1.285 (-2.591)
|
-0.844 (-2.116)
|
-1.052 (-2.00)
|
0.313 (7.743)
|
0.287 (8.492)
|
0.269 (6.943)
|
0.135 (3.674)
|
0.292 (7.761)
|
|
ICRG
|
|
|
|
0.130 (1.285)
|
|
|
|
|
|
-0.42 1 (-6.366)
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.276 (4.183)
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.656 (8.641)
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.243 (4.031)
|
N. Obs
R2
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
0.604
|
0.720
|
0.661
|
0.777
|
0.658
|
The results above are significant since they come to confirm
the existence of a close connection between the quality of governance and
economic growth. It is noted that when one adds the governance variables of
Kaufmann, the R2 passes from 0,597 to 0,748 % with the introduction
of the Voice and Accountability indicator (VA), to 0,736% with the indicator of
Political Stability (PS), to 0,789% with the Government Effectiveness indicator
(GE), to 0,795% with the Regulatory Quality indicator (RQ), to 0,799% with the
Rule of Law indicator (RL) and finally to 0,799 % with the Corruption Control
indicator (CC). The corresponding estimated coefficients are positive and
statistically significant. The most significant are respectively the Regulatory
Quality (RQ), the Rule of Law (RL), the Government Effectiveness (GE), the
Voice and Accountability (VA), the Control of Corruption (CC) and finally
Political Stability (PS).
8 The choice of these variables has been made to
remain in the same context that the variables of KAUFMANN.
9 For each institutional variable, one makes the
average over the period 1996-2003.
These results come to corroborate those obtained by Kaufmann
and al. (1999) and Knack and Keefer (1995) who show that the indicators of
governance constitute relevant elements of the long run economic growth.
For the ICRG indicators, we also note that when the
institutional variables are added, the R2 passes from 0,597 to
0,604% with the introduction of the government stability indicator (GS), to
0,720 % with the corruption indicator (COR), to 0,66 1% with the laws and
orders indicator (LO), to 0,777% with the bureaucratic quality indicator (BQ)
and finally to 0,65 8 with the democratic accountability indicator (DA). All
these indicators present expected significant signs except the indicator of
government stability which is not significant.
One can note that these empirical results for all the 96
countries come to confirm those obtained by several authors like Barro (1991)
and Londregan and Poole (1992) for political stability, Mauro (1995) for
corruption and Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2004) for the indicator of rules
and laws.
That makes it possible to conclude that the determinants of
good governance, the capacity of the State to manage the resources effectively
and to formulate and implement policies and quality regulations, all of them
explain for the most part the long run economic performances of nations.
6. Conclusion
In this work on the relation between the governance and the
economic growth, we initially showed that the governance is a concept which
does not have a clear consensus of what it consists of and which it is a
concept difficult to define and to measure. In the second time, we showed
through the existing literature that good governance is presented, during these
last years, like a very significant element in the determination of the longrun
economic performances. We also showed through the existing literature that the
elements of good governance offer an environment favourable for capital
accumulation and later on for economic growth. That was confirmed in our
empirical study which enabled us to show the existence of a close link between
the quality of governance and
economic growth for 96 countries between 1996 and 2003. Our
principal empirical results suggest that the quality of governance, under its
various aspects, is presented in the form of a relevant factor for the economic
growth.
A limit which we can attribute to our work is the use of the
indicators of governance without taking their limits into account. Indeed, the
indicators of governance are based on perceptions and are determined by
subjective opinions. Moreover, the absence of a subjacent conceptual framework
or governance theory to identify the causes of the results of the governance
reflected in the indicators, lacks clearness about the reasons for which such
country obtains such result for such indicator. It is thus paradoxical that the
financial backers and the investors judge and sometimes punish the developing
countries for an absence perceived of transparent governance on the basis of so
complex indicators.
Bibliographie
Acemoglu D., Johnson S. & Robinson J., «Institutions as
the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth», NBER Working Paper 10481
(2004).
AL-Marhubi F., «The Determinants of Governance: A
Cross-Country Analysis», Contemporary Economic Policy, 2:3 (2004),
394-406.
Alesina A. & Perotti R., «Political Instability and
Economic growth», Journal of Economic Growth, (1996).
Arndt C. & Oman C. « Les indicateurs de gouvernance:
Usages et Abus», Centre de développement de l'organisation de
coopération et de développement économique, OCDE
(2006).
Aron J., «Growth and Institutions: A Review of the
Evidence», The World Bank Research Observer, 15:1 (2000),
99-135.
Barro R., «Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of
Countries», Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (1991),
407-443.
Barro R., «Democracy and Growth», Journal of
Economic Growth, 1:1 (1996), 1-27. Barro R., «Determinants of
Economic Growth, A Cross Country Empirical Study», MIT Press,
Cambridge, MA (1997).
Cannet R., «Qu'est ce que la gouvernance?»,
Conférence prononcée dans le cadre du Séminaire : Les
nouveaux modes de gouvernance et la place de la société civile,
organisé par le Service aux collectivités de l'UQAM,
Montréal, Ecomusée du fier monde (2004).
Chtourou N & Feki R., «Analyse de la Gouvernance et
de son impact sur la Croissance : Cas des Pays Partenaires de la
Méditerranée». A paraître dans la Revue Canadienne
d'Etudes du Développement, Université d'Ottawa, Canada
(2004).
Clague C., Keefer P., Knack S & Olson M.,
«Contract-Intensive Money: Contrast Enforcement, Property Rights, and
Economic Performance », Journal of Economic Growth, 4(2)
(1996).
Demetriades, P. & Law S. H., (2006) «Finance,
institutions and economic development» International Journal of
Finance & Economics, 11:3 (2006),
245-2 60.
Easterly W. & Levine R., «Tropics, Germs, and Crops:
How Endowments Affect Economic Development», NBER Working Paper 9106,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass (2002).
Grier K-B & Tullock G (19989) «An Empirical Analysis
of Cross-National Economic Growth, 1951-80», Journal of Monetary
Economics, vol. 24, 259-76.
Hall R E & Jones CH I (1999), «Why do some countries
produce some much more output per worker than others?», The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Février 1999.
Helliwell J., «Empirical Linkages Between Democracy and
Economic Growth», British Journal of Political Science, 24 (1994),
225-248.
Hewitt de Alcantara, «Du bon usage du concept de
gouvernance», Revue internationale des sciences sociales (RISS) 1 55
(1998).
Isham, J, Kaufmann D & Lant P., «Civil liberties,
democracy, and the performance of government projects», World Bank
Economic Review, 11:2 (1997), 2 19-242.
Jutting J. (2003), «Institutions and Development: A Critical
Review», Working Papers N°2 10, OECD Development Center
(2003).
Kaufmann D. & Kraay A., «Aggregation Governance
Indicators», Policy Research Working Paper 2195, World Bank, Policy
Research Department, Washington, D.C, (1999).
Kaufmann D., Kraay A. & Zoido-Lobaton P., «Governance
Matters», World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2196
(1999).
Kaufmann D., Kraay A. & Mastruzzi M., «Governance
Matters III, Governance
Indicators for 1996-2002», World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Processed (2004). Knack S. & Keefer P., «Institutions and
Economic Performance: cross country
test using alternative International measures»,
Economics and Politics, 7(3)
(1995), 207-22 7.
Knack S., «Governance and Growth: Measurement and
Evidence», Forum Series on the Role of Institutions in Promoting Economic
Growth, IRIS, Washington, D.C. (2002).
Kormendi, R.C., and P.G. Meguire, «Macroeconomic
Determinants of Growth: Cross-Country evidence,» Journal of
Monetary Economics, 141-163 (1985).
Law S. H. & Demetriades P., «Finance, Institutions and
Economic Growth», International Journal of Finance & Economics,
vol. 11(3) (2006), 245-260.
Londregan J-B & Poole K-T, «The Seizure of Executive
Power and Economic Growth: Some Additional Evidence», Political
Economy, Growth and Business Cycles, Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press (1992).
Mankiw, N Gregory & Romer, David & Weil, David N.,
"A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth," The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, MIT Press, 107(2) (1992), 407-3 7.
Mauro P., «Corruption and Growth», Quarterly
Journal of Economics 11(3) (1995). Mauro P., «The Effects of
Corruption on Growth Investment and Expenditure:
A Cross-Country Analysis», in Kimberly Ann Elliot,
Corruption and the Global
Economy, Washington DC, Institute for International Economics
(1995).
North D., «Institution, Institutional Change, and Economic
performance»,
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press (1999).
Rodrik D., «Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What
They Are and How to Acquire them», Harvard University, Paper prepared
for the International Monetary Fund Conference on Second-G eneration Reforms,
Washington, DC (1999).
Rodrik D., Subramanian A. & Trebbi F., «Institutions
Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic
Development», NBER Working Paper 9305. National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, Mass (2002).
Scully G., «The Institutional Framework and Economic
Development», Journal of Political Economy (1988).
Svensson J., «Investment, Property Rights and Political
Instability- Theory and Evidence», European Economic Review (1998).
Tanzi V., «The role of The State and The Quality of The
Public Sector», IMF Working Paper/00/36 (2000).
Wei S-J, «How Taxing is Corruption on International
Investors?», Review of Economics and Statistics (2000).
World Bank, World Development Report (2002): Building
Institutions for Markets. New York: Oxford University Press.
World Economic Survey, «Diverging Growth and
development», Nation Unis, Development Policy and Analysis Division
(2006).
Appendix 1:
List countries of the
sample
Albania Algeria Argentina
Australia Austria Bangladesh
Belgium Botswana
Brazil
Bulgaria Burkina Faso
Cameroon
Canada Chile
China
Colombia
Costa Rica
Czech Republic Denmark
Dominican Republic Ecuador
Egypt. Arab Rep.
El Salvador
Ethiopia Finland France Gabon Gambia. The
Germany
Ghana Greece Guatemala
|
Guinea Guinea-Bis sau
Haiti
Honduras Hungary Iceland India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic Rep. Ireland
Israel
Italy
J amaica Japan
Jordan
Kenya
Lebanon Luxembourg Madagascar
Malawi
Malaysia Mali
Mexico Morocco Mozambique Namibia Netherlands Nicaragua Norway
Pakistan Panama Paraguay
|
Peru
Philippines Poland
Portugal
Romania
Rus sian Federation
Saudi Arabia Senegal
Sierra Leone Singapore
Slovak Republic
South Africa Spain
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Sweden
Switzerland
Syrian Arab Republic Tanzania
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad and Tobago Tunisia
Turkey
Uganda
United Kingdom
United States Uruguay
Venezuela, RB Vietnam
Yemen, Rep. Zambia
|
Appendix 2:
Variables and sources
Variables Notations Sources
|
Dependent variable
|
GDP/capita Lny WDI, IFS
|
Basic variables
|
Labour force
|
LnLF
|
WDI (2005)
|
Physical accumulation of capital
|
LnK
|
WDI (2005)
|
Institutional Variables
|
Kaufmann
|
* Voice and Accountability * Political
Stability
* Government Effectiveness * Regulatory Quality
* Rule of Law
* Control of Corruption
|
VA PS
GE RQ RL
CC
|
Kaufmann D., A. Kraay, and Mr. Mastruzzi 2006.
|
ICRG
|
* Government Stability
* Corruption
* Laws and Orders
* Bureaucratic Quality
* Democratic Accountability
|
GS COR
LO BQ DA
|
www.prsgroup.com/icrg/
|
|