UNIVERSITY OF MAURITIUS
FACULTY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AND
HUMANITIES
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
FINA'N'Gre6rI, PZVZ.L.OMENT A'KD
Ze,ONOMIC, 9JZOWTIf: Taff 6A-SZ
OF
lZwillrl(Pf+
by DUSHIMUMUKIZA Deogratias
I n partial fulfillment of the requirements of the degree
of
Master of Arts in Economics
Project Supervisor: Assoc. Prof. JANKEE
Kheswar
FEBRUARY 2010
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
DEDICATION
This dissertation is dedicated to my beloved wife Louise
MUKESHIMANA, my beloved daughter Ariane IRASUBIZA, my parents Marthe NIYONSABA,
Samuel BUGINGO and my grand parents Abel SHAMURENZI and Berne NYIRAHUKU and to
all other relatives.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
DECLARATION
UNIVERSITY OF MAURITIUS
PROJECT/DISSERTATION SUBMISSION FORM
Name: DUSHIMUMUKIZA DEOGRATIAS
|
Student ID:0826399
|
Programme of Studies:SH 540
|
Module Code/Name: MA ECONOMICS
|
Title of Project/Dissertation: FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT
AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE CASE OF RWANDA
|
Name of Supervisor(s): Assoc.Prof. JANKEE KHESWAR
|
Declaration:
In accordance with the appropriate regulations, I hereby submit
the above dissertation for examination and I declare that:
(i) I have read and understood the sections on
Plagiarism and Fabrication and Falsification of Results found
in the University's «General Information to Students» Handbook
(2009/2010) and certify that the dissertation embodies the results of my own
work.
(ii) I have adhered to the `Harvard system of referencing' or a
system acceptable as per «The University of Mauritius Referencing
Guide» for referencing, quotations and citations in my dissertation. Each
contribution to, and quotation in my dissertation from the work of other people
has been attributed, and has been cited and referenced.
(iii) I have not allowed and will not allow, anyone to copy my
work with the intention of passing it off as his or her own work.
(iv) I am aware that I may have to forfeit the
certificate/diploma/degree in the event that plagiarism has been detected after
the award.
(v) Notwithstanding the supervision provided to me by the
University of Mauritius, I warrant that any alleged act(s) of plagiarism during
my stay as registered student of the University of Mauritius is entirely my own
responsibility and the University of Mauritius and/or its employees shall under
no circumstances whatsoever be under any liability of any kind in respect of
the aforesaid act(s) of plagiarism.
|
|
Date:05/02/2010
|
Signature:
|
ABSTRACT
The study was intended to test the impact of financial
development on economic growth for Rwanda over the period 1964 to 2005. Four
measures of financial development are used including measures of financial
deepening and financial sophistication. We found out a significant positive
effect of financial deepening on economic growth, a bi-directional negative
relationship between financial sophistication and economic growth and no
significant evidence of the ratio of credit of banking institutions to total
domestic credit, and the ratio of credit to private sector to total domestic
credit, in promoting economic growth.
The observed failure of credit to private sector in promoting
economic growth suggests important policy implication on credit allocation
among private sector, and the failure of financial sophistication to affect
positively economic growth needs a further research on best proxies of
financial innovation in Rwanda.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
Various persons deserve a vote of thanks in as far as the
accomplishment of this study is concerned. I have a pleasure to mention some of
them: I am heavily indebted to Assoc. Prof. Jankee Kheswar for his professional
guidance and advices that made this work a success.
While at the University of Mauritius, I received a lot of
assistance from staff in the Department of Statistics and Economics. These
include the Dean of the Faculty, Professor Sobhee Sanjeev, former Head of
Department of Economics and Statistics Dr. Ancharaz Vinaye and Mrs. Parveen
Salamut, the Administrative Officer. I would like to extend my heartfelt
gratitude to my lecturers in the programme, namely: Dr. V. Tendrayen-Ragoobur
and Dr. Nowbutsing M. Baboo for their invaluable knowledge they delivered
without any reserve. The same acknowledgements extend to all Lecturers of JFE.
My special thanks go to AERC and its staff for invaluable assistance on both
financial and academic side, without them this study would not exist.
I am gratefully to my colleagues, Mohamed Alie Bangura, from
the University of Botswana for the academic materials he provided whose added
value to this study can not be estimated and Marie Amanda Guimbeau from the
University of Mauritius for her kind assistance which was invaluable for
someone in a foreign country. Indeed I cannot forget to mention my colleagues
Wilson Ngyendo, Wilson K. Karuhanga, and Mustapha J. for their immeasurable
comments.
My thanks are extended to all my family members in large and
specifically my parents Marthe Niyonsaba, Samuel Bugingo, Abel Shamurenzi,
Berne Nyirahuku, my in-laws family Gaspard Munyanzira and Annonciata
Nyirabaziga for moral support they extended during my stay in a foreign
country.
I owe most profound thanks and recognition to my beloved wife
Louise Mukeshimana for the sacrifice she made by accepting our separation for
two years after one year of wedding. Without her consent, I would not have gone
for this course. May this achievement reflect the cost of her sacrifice.
In spite of all these numerous assistance from various persons,
the errors, shortcomings and opinions expressed in this study are entirely
mine.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
DEDICATION ii
DECLARATION iii
ABSTRACT iv
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT v
LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES ix
LIST OF APPENDICES x
LIST OF ACCRONYMS xi
CHAPTER 1 1
INTRODUCTION 1
1.0 Introduction 1
1.1 Statement of the problem 1
1.2 Research questions 2
1.3 Research objectives 2
1.3.1 General Objective 2
1.3.2 Specific objectives 2
1.4 Research hypotheses 3
1.5 Significance of the study 3
1.6 Scope of the study 3
1.7 Organization of the study 3
CHAPTER 2 4
REVIEW OF LITERATURE ON FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC
GROWTH 4
2.0 Introduction 4
2.1. Measuring financial development 4
2.1.1 Proxies of financial depth 5
2.1.2 Proxy for financial sophistication 6
2.1.3 Other measures of financial development 6
2.2 Relationship between financial development and economic
growth 7
2.2.1 Theoretical link between financial development and economic
growth 7
2.2.2 Empirical literature review on the link between financial
development and
economic growth 12
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
2.3 Conclusion 16
CHAPTER 3 17
OVERVIEW OF THE RWANDAN FINANCIAL SECTOR 17
3.0 Introduction 17
3.1. Overview over the Rwandan economy 17
3.2 The Rwandan financial sector 19
3.2.1 Banking sector 20
3.2.2 Microfinance institutions 21
3.2.3 Insurance and pension funds 22
3.2.4 Financial markets 22
3.2.5 Financial liberalization in Rwanda 22
3.2.6 Monetary policy in Rwanda 23
3.3 Comparison of financial development within EAC 25
3.3.1 Ratio of Liquid liabilities (M3) to GDP 25
3.3.2 Claims on private sector to GDP ratio 26
3.3.3 Domestic credit to GDP ratio 26
3.4 Conclusion 27
CHAPTER 4 28
METHODOLOGY 28
4.0 Introduction 28
4.1 Meaning and rationale of the model used 28
4.2 Model specification and rationale of variables 28
4.3. Model estimation 29
4.3.1 Stationarity and cointegration 29
4.3.2 Granger causality tests 30
4.3.3. Variance decomposition and Impulse response 30
4.4. The data source and measurement 30
4.5 Conclusion 30
CHAPTER 5 31
MODEL ESTIMATION AND FINDINGS 31
5.0 Introduction 31
5.1 Test for stationarity 31
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
5.2 Test for cointegration 32
5.3 Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) 34
5.4 The Engle-Granger test 36
5.5 Impulse responses and variance decompositions 37
5.5.1 Variance decomposition 37
5.5.2 Impulse response models 41
5.6 Discussion of findings 41
5.7 Conclusion 43
CHAPTER 6 44
CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS 44
6.0 Introduction 44
6.1 Summary of findings 44
6.2 Policy recommendations 45
6.3 Areas for further research 46
REFERENCES 47
APPENDICES 52
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES
TABLES
TABLE1: TRENDS IN AVERAGE OF PER CAPITA GDP 18
TABLE 2: ADF TEST STATISTICS IN LEVELS 31
TABLE 3: ADF TEST STATISTICS WITH FIRST DIFFERENCE 32
TABLE 4: NUMBER OF COINTEGRATING RELATIONS BY MODEL, AT 5% LEVEL*
33
TABLE 5: UNRESTRICTED COINTEGRATING RANK TEST (TRACE) 34
TABLE 6: SIGNIFICANT VECTOR ERROR CORRECTION ESTIMATES 35
TABLE 7: F-STATISTICS FOR VECM 35
TABLE 8: MARGINAL SIGNIFICANCE LEVELS ASSOCIATED WITH JOINT
F-TEST 37
TABLE 9: VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF GRATE 38
TABLE 10: VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF DEPTH 38
TABLE 11: VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF SOPHT 39
TABLE 12: VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF BANK 40
TABLE 13: VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF PRIVATE 40
FIGURES
FIGURE 1: EVOLUTION IN RATION OF LIQUID LIABILITIES IN EAC 25
FIGURE 2: EVOLUTION IN AVERAGE OF CLAIMS ON PRIVATE SECTOR TO GDP
IN EAC 26 FIGURE 3: EVOLUTION IN AVERAGE RATIO OF DOMESTIC CREDIT TO GDP IN
EAC 27
LIST OF APPENDICES
Appendix A: Comparison of financial development in EAC Table A.1:
Average ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP in EAC
Table A.2: Average ratio of claims on private sector to GDP in
EAC Table A.3: Average domestic credit to GDP ratio in EAC
Appendix B: Granger causality test
Appendix C: Vector Error Correction Estimates, model 4 in Eviews
Appendix D: Impulse responses
Table D.1: Response of GRATE
Table D.2: Response of DEPTH
Table D.3: Response of SOPHT
Table D.4: Response of BANK
Table E.5: Response of PRIVATE
Appendix E: Data used in regression
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
LIST OF ACCRONYMS
ACH: Automated Clearing House
ADF: Augmented Dickey-Fuller
AERC: African Economic Research Consortium
AIC: Akaike Information Criteria
AR: Auto Regressive Models
ATMs: Automatic Teller Machines
BACAR: Banque Continentale Africaine au Rwanda
BCDI: Banque de Commerce et du Développement Industriel
(now ECOBANK) BCR: Banque Commerciale du Rwanda
BK: Banque de Kigali
BPR S.A: Banque Populaire du Rwanda, Société
Anonyme CIA: Central Intelligence Agency
CMAC: Capital Market Advisory Council
COGEAR: Compagnie Générale d'Assurance et de
Réasurance COOPECS: Coopérative d'Epargne et de Crédit
CORAR: Compagnie Rwandaise d'Assurance et de Réasurance
DF: Dickey-Fuller
DRC: The Democratic Republic of Congo (Former ZaÏre) DSA:
Development Studies Association
EAC: East African Community
EDPRS: Economic Development and Poverty Reduction Strategy GDP:
Gross Domestic Product
GNP: Gross National Product
H0: Nil hypothesis
H1: The alternative hypothesis
HQ: Hannan-Quinn criterion
I(0): Integrated of order 0 (stationary)
I(1): Integrated of order 1
IAER: Institute of Advanced Engineering and Research IFAD:
International Fund for Agricultural Development IFS: International Financial
Statistics
IMF: International Monetary Fund
KCB: Kenya Commercial Bank LDCs: Least Developed Countries
LR: Sequential modified LR test statistic
M1: Narrow money
M2: Broad money, money supply
M3: Liquid liabilities
MFIs: Microfinance Institutions MMI: Military Medical Insurance
NBR: National Bank of Rwanda OLS: Ordinary Least Squares OTC: Over- the-
Counter
RAMA: La Rwandaise d'Assurance Maladie
RWF: Rwandan Franc
SACCOs: Savings and Credit Cooperatives
SIMTEL: Société Interbancaire de Monétique
et de Télécompensation SONARWA: Société Nationale
d'Assurance au Rwanda
SORAS: Société Rwandaise d'Assurance
SSFR: Social Security Fund for Rwanda.
UBPR: Union des Banques Populaires du Rwanda (Cooperative
Bank)
UNDP: United Nations Development Program
US$: United State Dollar
VAR: Vector Autoregression Model VECM: Vector Error Correction
Model
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
CHAPTER 1
INTRODUCTION
1.0 I ntroductio
Since the views of Schumpeter (1911) on the role of financial
development on economic growth, strengthened by empirical works of McKinnon
(1973) and Shaw (1973), and invaluable contribution of Levine (1997) who
portrayed the functions through which financial development may affect economic
growth, a bulk of studies have been conducted across regions and countries to
provide further evidence on the link between financial development and economic
growth. It is in this spirit we have undertaken this study to determine whether
there is evidence of relationship between financial development and economic
growth in Rwanda.
This chapter presents the knowledge gap to be filled, research
questions and objectives alongside the hypotheses of the study. Moreover, the
chapter shows at what extend the study is relevant for Rwanda, highlights the
scope and the organization of the study.
1.1 Statement of the problem
The economic growth has been a major concern of the government
of Rwanda by putting a lot of effort to sustain Rwandan economy and to improve
social welfare. Even though Rwandan economy has recovered considerably since
the 1994 genocide; the GDP per capita is still low, around 460 US$, and over 56
percent of the population live under the poverty line. The agricultural sector,
employing more than two-third of the population is underdeveloped and its
contribution to GDP is small, accounting less than 35 percent. The industry
sector too seems not to be in a good position to be an alternative measure
since it remained on infant stage and its contribution to GDP has never reached
20 percent.
Apparently, the alternative way to speed up economic
development is through a developed financial system. However, Rwandan
financial system remains shallow and financial depth is below the
Sub-Saharan and East African
averages. The financial sophistication is impaired by a low
level of financial innovation though the country is being known as having above
average growth in information technology in the region. Moreover, Rwanda does
not have a developed supply of capital market-based long-term debt
instruments.
With undeveloped financial sector, it is unlikely for Rwanda
to attain a sustainable development. The purpose of this study is to find out
how the level of financial development is linked to the economic growth so as
to bring to the light, emphasis and pinpoint the crucial, critical and
paramount importance of financial development to the economic development
process of Rwanda.
1.2 Research questions
Throughout our study we will try to find solutions to the
following questions:
1. Does the level of financial development matter for Rwandan
economic
growth?
2. Is there a bi-directional influence between financial
development and economic growth?
1.3 Research objectives
1.3.1 General Objective
The main objective of this study is to assess the impact of
financial development on economic growth for Rwanda to determine whether
financial sector can be viewed as an alternative pillar for future economic
growth especially within the Vision 2020 frame work.
1.3.2 Specific objectives
1. To investigate whether the increase in credit to the private
sector had led to improvements in growth rate of GDP.
2. To determine whether the expansion of credit allocated by
banking institutions versus credit allocated by Central bank has led to
increase in growth rate of GDP.
3. To investigate whether the financial innovation has a
positive impact on GDP.
4.
To investigate whether the increase of credit to private sector
versus credit to public sector exerts a positive effect on economic growth.
5. To determine whether there is a bi-directional feedback
between proxies of financial development and economic growth.
1.4 Research hypotheses
a) The level of financial depth and sophistication positively
affects economic growth.
b) The increased share of banking institutions in credit
allocation has contributed to rise in growth rate of GDP.
c) The rise in share of credit to private sector in total
domestic credit is reflected in the growth of economic activities.
d) A bi-directional influence exists between the proxies of
financial development and the rate of growth of real per capita GDP
1.5 Significance of the study
Studies conducted on cross-sectional and panel data analyses
revealed the absence or weak link between economic growth and financial
development in developing countries. To the best of our knowledge, this is the
first study which aims to ascertain whether Rwandan country case fits with
those findings. With a weak agriculture sector and an infant industry sector,
the study will determine if a developed financial sector can be a new pillar of
Rwandan economy.
1.6 Scope of the study
The study analyses the link between financial development and
economic growth in Rwanda and covers the period of 1964 to 2005. The period
starts with the creation of the Central bank and is sufficiently long and
allows comparison with other studies.
1.7 Organization of the study
The rest of the study is structured as follows: chapter two
gives brief review of literature on the subject. Chapter three describes the
evolution of the financial sector in Rwanda. Chapter four presents the
methodology used, in chapter five we report our results and in chapter six we
conclude.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
CHAPTER 2 REVIEW OF LITERATURE ON FINANCIAL
DEVELOPMENT AND
ECONOMIC GROWTH
2.0 I ntroductio
The causality effect between financial development and
economic growth has been a controversial issue for long years. Some researchers
have found a positive impact of financial development on economic growth,
others, in cross-country or geographical regions and income groups, have found
a significance relationship for some geographical regions and none in others,
especially for developing countries. Even though the link between financial
development and economic growth is accepted, the direction of causality is
still a debate. In this chapter, we present a review of literature on this
issue from both theoretical and empirical grounds.
2.1. Measuring financial development
We begin this section by defining what financial development
is by breaking it into two components: Financial deepening and financial
sophistication. Financial depth or deepening can be regarded as the measure of
the size of financial intermediaries. This follows the definition of McKinnon
(1973), Shaw (1973) and Levine and King (1993) where they define financial
deepening as the process which involves banking liberalization from state
control, reduction or abolition of credit rationing and marketization of
financial parameters in financially repressed economies.
On the other hand, financial sophistication is defined as the
act of creating and popularizing new financial instruments as well as new
financial technologies, institutions and markets (Tufano, 2002). The innovation
can be regarded into two areas: product or process innovation. In product
innovation, new derivatives, contracts, new corporate securities or new forms
of pooled investments products are created whereas in process innovation, new
means of distributing securities, processing or pricing transactions are
discovered and used widely.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
2.1.1 Proxies of financial depth
Many proxies have been used to measure the level of financial
depth. Some researchers simply used the ratio of monetary aggregates (M1, M2 or
M3) to GDP as a proxy of financial depth, depending on the level of financial
development of a country. This view is inspired by the work of Levine (1997) in
which financial depth was defined as the ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP.
In line with this view, Hassan and Jung-Suk (2007) used the
ratio of M3 to GDP as a proxy of financial depth. They argue that other
monetary aggregates like M1 and M2 may be poor proxies in economies with
underdeveloped financial system, where a high ratio of money to GDP exists
because money is used as store of value in the absence of other more attractive
alternatives.
Others prefer to use the ratio of money supply or the broad
money (M2) to GDP (Loayza et al, 2000). However, this measurement was exposed
to the criticism that deep financial market may cause a decrease in the M2/GDP
ratio in countries having developed capital markets. This situation can be seen
as less problematic than situations in developed countries with a dominant
banking sector (Sakutukwa, 2008).
A reasonable explanation of the weaknesses of the broad money
as measure of financial deepening has been provided by Firdu and Struthers
(2003) that with financial liberalization, capital inflows add to the funds
available for credit expansion by banking system. However, these foreign funds
do not increase money supply since they are excluded from it by definition.
Therefore, increase in credit expansion, which is a good indicator of financial
deepening, may not be reflected in the movements of the money supply in
financially deregulated economies with important capital inflows. In addition,
government borrowing from the banking system reduces the amount of credit
available to domestic private sector and may have a strong negative effect on
economic performance but this will not be reflected in the trends of money
supply.
To support challengers of the ratio of liquid liabilities as
proxy of financial depth, Zhang et al (2007) used the ratio of claims on
private enterprise to GDP as
proxy of financial depth in investigating on the financial
deepening-productivity nexus in China over the period 1987-2001, unlikely to
previous studies in China which used M2/GDP, total credit/GDP or banking
financial assets/GDP as proxy of financial depth. They argued that as financial
sector is gradually liberalized, the rising depth of financial intermediation
is most likely to be a result of commercialization of state banks and should be
closely related to the change in the relative share of bank financing between
state owned enterprises and a variety of newly emerged enterprises. Due to lack
of data, they proposed the ratio of claims on private sector to GDP as a better
proxy of financial depth.
Karima and Holden (2001) supported this view holding that
though the ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP (or M3/GDP) indicates the level
of the liquidity provided to the economy, a weakness is that it does not
reflect the allocation of savings and so may not be an accurate indicator of
the activities of financial intermediaries. The true measure of financial depth
remains an empirical issue.
2.1.2 Proxy for financial sophisticatio
If we consider the definition provided by Koðar (1995),
that financial sophistication is brought about by financial innovations and
affects the nature and composition of monetary aggregates, it is reasonable to
measure it by the ratio of M2 to M1. This is because financial sophistication
will be characterized by introduction of credit cards, e-banking, more use of
checking accounts and all these are embodied in M2. Liu et al (1994) noted that
as the ratio of M2 to M1 increases, the more the technological improvements in
banking system.
2.1.3 Other measures of financial development
Putting aside the distinction between financial depth and
sophistication, other indicators have been added as candidate to represent the
level of financial development within a country:
Levine (1997) included three extra proxies, namely: BANK,
PRIVATE, and PRIVY, defined as follows:
>
BANK: It is the ratio of bank credit divided
by bank credit plus central bank domestic assets and measures the degree to
which the central bank versus commercial banks are allocating credit.
> PRIVATE: It is the ratio of credit
allocated to private enterprises to total domestic credit (excluding credit to
banks) and measures the level of financial services.
> PRIVY: It equals credit to private
enterprises divided by GDP.
PRIVATE and PRIVY were chosen to correct weaknesses of BANK
measure because not only financial intermediaries provide financial functions
and the volume of credit given by banks may be flowing to public institutions
which does not indicate the level of financial penetration. Unfortunately,
PRIVATE and PRIVY could not correct for the weakness of considering only
financial functions delivered by financial institutions.
Other indicators used are: Gross domestic saving to GDP
(Hassan and JungSuk, 2007), some indicators of stock market development like
stock market capitalization, turnover ratio and the number of listed companies
(Yongfu, 2005). Fry (1989) identifies three quantitative measures of financial
conditions specific to developing countries, based on McKinnon (1973) and Shaw
(1973) theories of financial liberalization. These are: the real deposit rate
of interest, population per bank branch and a financial intermediation ratio.
He added investment as percentage of GDP and change in GDP to investment ratio
as proxies of investment efficiency and net saving ratio respectively.
2.2 Relationship between financial development and
economic growth
This section goes through the theoretical and empirical
relationship between financial development and economic growth as identified by
scholars.
2.2.1 Theoretical link between financial development and
economic growth
Views on the link between financial development and economic
growth can be divided into three hypotheses: The supply leading, demand leading
and no link hypotheses.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
2.2.1.1 Supply leading hypothesis
According to this view, the financial sector deepening leads
to economic growth. The explanation is that, according to Levine (1997),
financial development has five financial functions through which it affects
economic growth. These functions, shared by Bodie et al (2008), are:
· Producing cheaper information about possible investment
and allocating capital;
· Monitoring firms and exerting corporate governance;
· Trading, diversification and management of risk;
· Mobilizing and pulling of savings;
· Easing exchange of goods and services
The effect of financial innovations on economic growth is
presented by Tufano (2002) in three functions:
· Financial innovations mitigate the lack of free
movement of funds across time and space in incomplete markets and allow risk
sharing among individuals.
· Innovations address agency concerns and information
asymmetry with invention of new contracts like common stock which provides some
mechanisms to squeeze information from firms, a warranty offered by a seller
and income bonds linked to the availability of accounting information.
· They minimize searching and marketing cost: This is the
role of ATMs, smart cards, ACH technologies and many other new businesses.
These financial functions influence savings, investment
decisions, technological innovations and hence economic growth. Better
functioning financial systems ease the external financing constraints that
impede firm and industrial expansion. This implies that the creation of
financial institutions and their services occurs in advance of demand for them.
Thus, the availability of financial services stimulates the demand for these
services by the entrepreneurs in the modern, growth-inducing sectors.
This hypothesis has received a great number of supporters:
Schumpeter (1911) argued that the financial sector deepening leads to
economic growth through
productively making out and funding economically efficient
projects. He put emphasis on banking sector which performs the function of
intermediation between possessors of productive means and those who wish to use
them and this is a key determinant in understanding capital formation.
McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) developed a robust model of
financial development appropriate to LDCs, through which financial development
affects positively economic growth. Known as complementarity hypothesis, the
McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) model is based on the positive relationship
between real deposit rate of interest and investment, contrary to previous
thought where this link was negative. The model stresses the negative effects
of financial repression on economic growth, characterizing developing
economies.
In fact, they argue that financial repression through
interest rate ceilings, directed credit, exchange rate controls, control on the
source of finance of banking institutions and other forms of financial
repression result in negative real deposit rate of interest. This reduces the
supply of loanable funds and force banking institutions to apply credit
rationing in front of excess demand of loanable funds. The outcome is the
allocation of funds not based on the productivity of investment rather on other
factors like transaction costs and apparent risk of default. This scenario
leads to economy being allocating credit to non productive investments which
decreases investment productivity and efficiency, thus slowing down economic
growth.
Financial liberalization was proposed as a model of financial
development which leads to economic growth through increase in real deposit
rate of interest, raising the saving mobilization and the financing of the
economy both from internal and external source, as a result of capital
liberalization. This model has been a central point for analysing effect of
financial development on economic growth, where most studies compare before and
post financial liberalization periods. They include Jankee (2006) in Mauritius,
Abebe (1990) in African LDCs, Demetriades and Luintel (1996) in India, Margaret
(2004) in USA and many others.
In the same idea of financial liberalization, Fry (1997)
explained the DiamondDybving financial intermediation in an
overlapping-generations model developed by Bencivenga, Smith, Greenwood and
Smith, and Levine. With banks acting as intermediaries between savers and
borrowers, avoiding uncertainty which leads to resource misallocation and
offering liquidity to savers, they produce higher capital/labour ratios and
higher rates of economic growth.
Levine and Zervos (1996) recognise that liquid stock markets
and growth banking sector lead to economic growth through increase in capital
accumulation and production.
According to Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990), financial sector
development will direct funds to higher yielding projects with the great
involvement of information: the financial intermediaries produce better
information, improve resource allocation and hence foster growth. Basically,
the role of financial sector in easing access to information and leading to
efficient financial market raises the quality of investment, leading to
technological innovation and consequently to economic growth.
Cameron (1961) confirmed the supply leading hypothesis after
his study in France where he found a positive impact of financial development
on economic development through mortgage.
2.2.1.2 Demand leading hypothesis
The supply leading hypothesis has not received unanimity
among economists. Some influential economists such as Robinson (1952), and
Friedman and Schwartz (1963) argued that the development of the financial
sector is induced by economic growth such that it comes as a result of higher
demand of financial services. Robinson supports that economic growth creates
supply for financial services which would cause a financial development. Levine
(2001) argued that economic growth may reduce the fixed cost of joining
financial intermediaries and the more people join, hence financial sector may
be caused by improvement in economic growth.
Kuznets (1955) supports this idea by saying that finance does
not exert a significant impact on economic growth but rather when the economy
grows, more financial institutions, financial products (financial innovation)
and services come into the market in response to higher demand of financial
services. For Thanvegelu (2004), enterprise guides then finance follows.
2.2.1.3 No link or negative effect
hypothesis
This hypothesis may be regarded as the criticism of the views
above about the link between financial development and economic growth. The
footstep of this theory may be drawn for the statement of Lucas (1988), who
noted that economists have a tendency to overemphasize the role of financial
factors in the process of economic growth. It is possible that the development
of the financial sector markets may result as an impediment to growth when it
induces volatility and discourages risk unenthusiastic investors from
investing. Singh (1997) and Mauro (1995) noted that financial innovation allows
risk reduction and may lower the precautionary savings and investments, thus
slowing down economic growth.
A radical criticism of the role of financial development to
economic growth mainly through financial liberalization comes from
neo-structuralists. They refuted the model of financial deregulation developed
by McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) by attacking the assumption of competitive
market in banking institutions embodied in the model. The point is that in most
developing countries, the financial industry operates in oligopolistic or
collusive model without an apparent competition as assumed by McKinnon-Shaw's
theory.
Stiglitz (1994) argued that financial liberalization leads to
market failures rooted from costly information which leads to externalities
like a generalized bank crisis following a bankruptcy in one or two banks. He
supports some measures of financial regulation like keeping interest rates
below their market equilibrium, as corrective measures which will in addition
improve the efficiency of capital allocation. In addition, financial repression
was not the only source of credit rationing.
Again Stiglitz and Andrew (1981) demonstrated that other
credit rationing may exist in equilibrium situation, as a result of other
factors outside interest rate ceilings, like asymmetry information, collusion
in banking sector which set deposit rate below the market equilibrium,
consideration of transaction costs, anticipated risk of default, quality of
collateral and pressure from bank managers.
This view has been supported by many researchers like Buffie
(1989) who stated that if we give permission to reactions in markets, then
financial liberalization will be a dangerous enterprise. Diaz-Alejandro (1985)
summarized the effects of financial liberalization as «Good-bye financial
repression, hello financial crash» because in most developing countries,
financial crisis followed financial liberalization policies undertaken by
governments and the results were worse.
Fry (1989) lists a group of neo-structuralists who questioned
the validity of McKinnon-Shaw hypothesis and demonstrated that banks cannot
intermediate as efficiently as curb markets between savers and lenders because
reserve requirements constitute a leakage in the process of financial
intermediation through commercial banks. The group includes Taylor Lance,
Sweder Van Wijnbergen, Akira Kohsaka among others.
According to them, in practice, financial liberalization is
likely to reduce the rate of economic growth by reducing total real supply of
credit available to business firms. In short, the opponents of financial
liberalization base their facts on various failures observed in many countries
after liberalization, which led to financial distress and crisis. The list of
countries is long but Argentina, Chile, Uruguay, Turkey and Philippines come on
the top.
2.2.2 Empirical literature review o n the link between
financial development and economic growth
The evidence on the link between financial development and
economic growth covers a variety of studies using time series analysis,
cross-country growth regressions, panel studies, etc.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
2.2.2.1 Cross=cou ntry cases
The cross-country case studies have been carried out by many
researchers: Levine and King (1993) and Levine and Zervos (1996) found that
higher levels of financial development are positively correlated with economic
development. Their findings suggest that the legal environment facing banks can
have a significant impact on economic growth through its effect on bank
behavior.
Michael and Giovanni (2001) examined whether there is
evidence of a causal link from capital account liberalization to financial
deepening and, through this channel, to overall economic growth on
cross-section of developed and developing countries, over the period 1986 to
1995, as well as over the period 1976 to 1995. With regard to the link between
financial development and GDP growth, they noted a statistically significant
and economically relevant positive effect of open capital accounts on financial
depth and economic growth. However, this effect seems to be concentrated among
industrial countries, whereas a little evidence was found in developing
countries for financial depth brought about by capital account liberalization
to affect positively economic growth.
In Africa, Douglas (2003) investigated evidence of the
finance growth nexus in a sample of emerging Sub-Saharan African countries
using cointegration and a vector error-correction model. He found that
financial development and economic growth are linked in the long-run in seven
of eight countries and causality test revealed unidirectional causality from
finance to growth in Ghana, Nigeria, Senegal, South Africa, Togo and Zambia.
For Ivory Coast and Kenya, the causality run from growth to finance, confirming
the demand leading hypothesis in the two countries.
2.2.2.2 Panel data cases
Starting by Africa, Kesseven et al (2007) brought new
evidence of finance-growth relationship from developing countries by analyzing
a sample of 44 African countries from 1979 to 2002. They used both static and
dynamic panel analysis and random effect and found that the financial
development has been contributing to the level of output though the
contribution was not at the same
level across countries. However, the contribution of financial
development was observed to be on the lesser extent as compared to the other
explanatory variables.
Karim and Holden (2001) conducted a panel of 30 developing
countries to test the supply leading hypothesis. Using the alternative measures
of bank development and stock market development, they found a strong positive
link between stock market development and economic growth. However, contrary to
the findings of Levine et al (2000), they found a negative association between
credit allocation and economic growth. The reasons were the failure of
financial deregulation due to absence of prerequisites for successful
deregulation.
Fry (1989) examined over 15 years saving behavior in 14 Asian
developing countries and 28 developing countries heavily indebted to the World
Bank. It was found that a 1 percent rise in real deposit rate of interest
raises national saving ratio by about 0.1 percent. On the effect of financial
liberalization on investment productivity, Fry found positive and significant
relationship between the incremental output/capital ratio and the real deposit
rate of interest and also the real deposit rate of interest and economic growth
in those Asian developing countries.
2.2.2.3 Country case=studies
Spears (1991) examined the causal relationship between
financial intermediation and economic growth in a sample of five Sub-Saharan
African countries (Burkina Fasso, Cameroon, Ivory Cost, Kenya and Malawi),
using Granger causality and two-distributed-lag regressions. He used two
measures of the financial development: the ratio of money supply to real per
capita GDP and the ratio of quasi-money to money supply. He found no causality
between the later and economic growth and these results may be attributable to
wrong measure used rather than absence of causality between financial
development and economic growth. But the causality from financial development
to economic growth was found when the ratio of money supply to GDP was used.
Team (2002) used a VECM in 13 Sub-Saharan African countries
and found from the cointegration analysis that there exists a long-run
relationship between financial development and economic growth in twelve out of
thirteen countries and the causality run from finance to growth in eight of the
countries taken in the sample. Six countries provided evidence of
bi-directional causality.
Demetriades and Luintel (1996) found a bi-directional
causality between financial deepening and economic growth in India and a
negative impact of banking sector control on economic growth, in the model
linking financial depth and banking deregulation to economic growth using Error
Correction Model. Zhang (2007) examined if regional productivity growth is
accounted for by the deepening process of financial development in China, using
provincial panel data, and found that after controlling for other variables,
the depth of financial intermediation exerts significantly positive influence
on productivity growth in China during 1987-2001. The financial
intermediation-growth nexus in post reform China was strongly supported.
2.2.2.4 Industry and firm level case studies
Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998), in a firm
level data, showed that larger banking systems and more liquid stock markets
allow firms to grow faster than it would be had been internal resources used to
finance their investments. Using industry level data across countries, Rajan
and Zingales (1998) found that external finance benefits more to their users
and allows firm to grow faster than firms which only resort to domestic
financial markets.
A different approach was taken by Beck et al (2006) by
examining the effect of the size of the industry in financial
development-economic nexus. Using industry data, they concluded that economies
dominated by small firms grow faster in developed financial system than large
firm-based economies.
Raymond and Love (2004) used data of 37 industries in 43
countries over the period 1980-1990, to analyze the link between financial
development and interindustry resource allocation in the short and long-run,
and found that in the short-run, financial institutions allocate resources to
any industry that has experienced a positive shock to growth opportunities
irrespective of his source
of financing, whereas in the long-run, in countries with well
developed financial institutions, industries which rely heavily on external
financing (Debt-finance instead of equity-finance) will have a comparative
advantage and will capture a larger share of total production in the
economy.
2.3 Co nclusio
The chapter examined three theoretical views about the link
between economic growth and financial development: the one stating that the
financial sector development leads to economic growth, another putting economic
growth ahead of financial development and lastly the view which does not
support the importance of financial development on economic growth. On the
empirical side, a strong positive role of financial development on economic
growth has been found mostly in developed countries, and a weak or absence of
link in developing countries. In some cases, the demand leading hypothesis has
not been supported. In the next chapter we present the Rwandan financial
sector.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
CHAPTER 3
OVERVIEW OF THE RWANDAN FINANCIAL SECTOR 3.0
Introduction
This chapter narrows the financial development issue to
Rwandan case and highlights the weaknesses as well as the strength of the
Rwandan financial system. To situate the level of financial development in
macroeconomic perspective, a brief review of Rwandan economy is first
presented. The chapter finishes with a comparison of the financial sector in
Rwanda with those of other country members of East African region where Rwanda
and Burundi were admitted in 2008.
3.1. Overview over the Rwandan economy
Rwanda is a small landlocked country in Central-East Africa,
with 26,338 square kilometers. Its GDP per capita was $ 62.95 in 1970 with a
population of 3.7 million, eight years after its independence from Belgium in
1962. The country is hampered by mountainous terrain and distance from the
sea.
Rwanda is among most densely populated countries in Africa.
In 2009, Rwanda was ranked 29th among densely countries in 239
countries with density of 379 people per square kilometer, far ahead of the
African average of 34 people per square kilometer. In 2009, the population was
9.998 million, growing at 2.8 %, compared to African average of 1.66 %, thus
putting increasing pressure on agriculture land and environment (United Nations
Population Division, 2008).
Rwanda's economy is essentially rural; nearly 81% of the
population lives in rural areas (United Nations Statistic Division, 2009) and
derives its livelihood from subsistence agriculture, cultivating coffee and tea
for export with rudiment methods. Besides agriculture, there is exploitation of
scarce natural resources in some regions like cassiterite, wolframite, and
methane recently discovered in Lake Kivu.
Rwandan economy has been improving since 2000 with an
increasing growth rate especially for the last four years, when the country
maintained an average
growth rate vis-à- vis many African countries over the
period 2005-2008. In fact, the growth rate was 7.2 % in 2005, 7.3% in 2006, 7.9
% and 11.2 % in 2007 and 2008 respectively accumulating into an average growth
rate of 8.4 % above the African average rate of 5.82% during this period. In
addition, the country became the third, after Angola and Ethiopia (IMF, 2009).
Moreover, Rwanda has made considerable efforts in improving living conditions
of her population. Poverty has fallen by 3%, from 60% of the population living
under the poverty line in 2000/2001 to 56.9% in 2006 but leaving 37.9% still
extremely poor (IFAD website). However, Rwanda's development indicators are
still below the African and East African averages, as indicated by the table
below:
Table1: Trends i n average of per capita GDP
Indicator
|
Country
|
1970=
1980
|
1981=
1990
|
1991=
2000
|
2000=
2008
|
Overall average
|
Per capita GDP (in US$)
|
Rwanda
|
147.4
|
323.5
|
268.2
|
276.6
|
250
|
|
489.21
|
768.9
|
733.9
|
1029.8
|
734.59
|
|
232.45
|
313.9
|
278.8
|
346.76
|
288.69
|
Growth rate of GDP (%)
|
Rwanda
|
5.54
|
2
|
3.2
|
7.13
|
4.36
|
|
3.08
|
3.26
|
3.17
|
5.27
|
3.55
|
|
3.87
|
2.14
|
2.82
|
5.83
|
3.5
|
Share of Gross capital formation in GDP (in %)
|
Rwanda
|
14.45
|
18.71
|
13.35
|
17.27
|
15.84
|
|
29.80
|
26.07
|
20.05
|
24.26
|
25.32
|
|
22.29
|
17.77
|
16.26
|
19.15
|
18.94
|
|
Source: Author's calculations from data
provided by United Nations Statistics Division, CIA World Fact books and World
Development indicators Database.
As the table indicates, for the period 1981-1990 Rwanda
reached the highest average per capita GDP with $323.5 compared to the average
of $276.6 during the recent period ranging from 2000-2008. In addition, it is
only in this period where its per capita GDP and the share of Gross capital
formation in GDP was
above East African average. This was mainly due to political
stability and favorable weather that prevailed during that time which made
agricultural sector to contribute a lot in GDP.
The period 1990-2000 was marked by war of four years
(1990-1994), the genocide of 1994 in which more than one million lost their
lives and insecurity which affected the north (1996-1998). This explains the
decrease in above indicators. Despite this situation, the growth rate of GDP
exceeded African and East African average, as the country was trying to
recover. Although the recent period was marked by the highest per capita GDP in
2008 with $ 458.49, but the period was characterized by a low per capita GDP in
the period ranging from 2001-2003, a figure less than $200.
It is worth to say that it is in 2008 where the country
recovered and passed over the level of per capita GDP reached before the
genocide, that of 1988 with $360.87. The per capita GDP has been declining as
from 1989, one year before the beginning of the war of 1990, up to 1994 from
$360.87 in 1988 to $207.43 in 1994. Since 1995, the economic growth started to
recover and currently, though the per capita GDP is still low, but Rwanda is
among top performing in Africa with the growth rate currently above both
African and East African average.
Many reasons explain the poverty of the country: being a
landlocked country, on this it added the bad governance which has characterized
the country since its independence, war, genocide and insecurity, lack of
natural resources, little skilled human capital, as per year 2005, less than 1%
of the population had a tertiary education, and a low level of investment.
3.2 The Rwandan financial sector
We analyse the financial sector by looking at the banking
sector, MFIs, insurance companies and financial markets. We begin by mentioning
that the Rwandan financial sector can be traced back from the creation of the
Central Bank, National Bank of Rwanda and issue of the local currency, Rwandan
Franc (RWF) in April 1964.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
3.2.1 Banking sector
The development of the financial sector before the genocide
of 1994 was slow. At the time, only 3 commercial banks and 2 specialized banks
operated with a total of less than 20 branches in the country, and one
microfinance (UBPR) with around 146 branches. The war and the genocide affected
heavily the banking sector: The genocide itself resulted in closure of the
Central bank for 4 months. The former government left the country in 1994 for
the DRC, after committing the genocide, with two-thirds of the national
monetary base in addition to US $7 million in cash which was taken from the
UBPR (Alson et al, 2001). Consequently, it took two years for this bank to
reopen, in 1996. Moreover, almost both physical and human capital of all banks
were destroyed during the genocide.
The post genocide period was marked by increase in number of
banks, where in 2002 there were 6 commercial banks with 28 branches, 2
specialized banks and 1 union of financial institutions (UBPR) with 148
branches (NBR, 2004). In 2007, commercial banks operated only 38 branches,
making only 7 % of all branches of financial institutions and by the end of
2008, 8 commercial banks, 2 specialized banks and 1 Microfinance bank were
operating.
However, there was a lack of competition as three banks (BCR,
BK and ECOBANK) held 66% market share before the licensing of UBPR as
commercial bank in 2008. This situation has led to high interest rate spreads
(8.6% in 2005), a modest 16% per annum growth in deposits over the past 5
years, and lending primarily to a core group of about 50 relatively large
customers concentrated in Kigali and a few sectors (Murgatroyd et al, 2007).
The penetration of banking sector is very low, and worse in
rural areas. The survey conducted by FinMark Trust in 2008 showed that in
general, only 14 percent of the active population use banks, 7% use MFIs, 26%
are informally served and 52% are financially excluded. In rural areas, less
than 6 percent of the population hold savings account in a formal finance
institution. Indeed, penetration of domestic credit to the private sector is
underperforming, with 11
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
percent of GDP, compared to 18 percent of GDP for peer countries
(NBR, 2008).
Several reasons explain the underdevelopment of financial
services. The weak culture of savings among the people is due to low level of
per capita income in the country. In fact, in 2009 Rwanda was ranked
21st poorest of the least developed countries in the world and 56.9
percent of its population lives on less than US$0.45 equivalent a day, the
poverty threshold in Rwanda (IMF, 2009).
Secondly, a high spread between the deposit rate (around 7%)
and a lending rate (around 16%) does not provide an incentive to the public to
save. Many bank accounts are used as a payment mechanism for employees. It is
important to note that due to relative higher penetration of UBPR, it has been
upgraded to commercial bank in 2008 and became BPR S.A, and that KCB, a new
regional bank from Kenya has been licensed.
3.2.2 Microfi na nce institutions
Microfinance initiatives mushroomed from 2002, primarily as a
response to the weak involvement of the traditional banks in small and micro
enterprises, and rural areas. Sixty-three microfinance institutions were
licensed in 2006 (Habyalimana, 2007).
In 2009, the microfinance sub-sector consisted of around 125
MFIs including 111 COOPECS (Kantengwa, 2009). In June 2006, NBR estimated that
MFIs represented 24.18% of the total financing of the economy with RWF 59bn
(equivalent of $100 million) out of RWF 244bn of credit of the financial
institutions and 25% of savings mobilization. The mobilized savings amounted to
RWF 65bn (equivalent to around $.110 million) out of RWF 259bn. Informal
finance is so popular that 73 % of total population reported using informal
loans in 2005 (Habyalimana, 2007).
However, Microfinance institutions are inexperienced,
characterised by management with poor corporate governance, weak information
systems, important losses caused by poor internal organisation and a
mismanagement of their loan portfolio (Kantengwa, 2009). All these weaknesses
culminated into
the failure of nine microfinance institutions in 2006 with
total deposits of more than $5.3 million, leading to a general panic (NBR,
2007). To include rural population in the financial system, UMURENGE SACCOs was
introduced in the end of 2008, a saving scheme to be operating in each of 421
sectors.
3.2.3 Insurance and pension funds
This sector comprises 5 classic insurance companies (SONARWA,
SORAS, COGEAR, CORAR and Phoenix of Rwanda Assurance Company) and six insurance
brokers. In 2006, only about 3% of the active population held insurance policy.
In addition, there are three public medical insurance companies: RAMA, MMI and
Mutuelle de Santé and one private company, AAR Health Services, licensed
in 2008. The relatively well performing RAMA and MMI serve only 5% of the
population (NISR, 2008).
The pension sector is assured by one Public Pension fund
(SSFR) and 10 Growing Private Pension funds. The SSFR covers only 7.5% of
active population and on overall less than 8% of the active population is under
pension schemes (NBR, 2009).
3.2.4 Financial markets
In January 2008, Rwanda established a capital market with the
creation of an Over-The-Counter market operated and regulated by a Capital
Market Advisory Council (CMAC). However, its market capitalisation is still
very low as only $ 360, 000 has been traded in 15 transactions (the average of
$24,000 in each transaction) and newspapers frequently reported that the OTC
has been silent due to lack of transactions recorded. The main reason is the
poverty of Rwandan citizen which does not allow the culture of saving where
even those who earn monthly salary are able to spend it for survival only. With
regard to market participants, Rwandan OTC has 7 members divided into three
categories: Stockbrokers, Dealers and Sponsors (CMAC website).
3.2.5 Financial liberalization i n Rwanda
Before the financial liberalization, tools of monetary policy
were mainly credit rationing, directed credit and interest rate controls.
The financial deregulation
was characterized by legal reforms affecting the nature of
central bank supervision and new tools of monetary policy were introduced like
regal reserve requirements and discount rate, alongside the abolition of
interest rate ceilings, directed credit and credit rationing as well.
The process of financial liberalization started in March 1995
by the liberalization of exchange rate and interest rate in 1996. In the same
year, banking structure was opened to foreign investment and entry requirements
for MFIs were relaxed. However, despite abolition of controls on interest
rates, the rigidity in the later is still observed, fluctuating around 16% for
lending and 7% for deposit rates of interest, due to oligopolistic nature of
the banking system.
The period 2004-2006 was characterized by take over of
nonperforming banks due to poor corporate governance. BACAR and BCDI were taken
over by FINABANK and ECOBANK respectively, and the government sold its majority
of share in BCR. In 2006, the spread of MFIs nationwide came as another step in
financial liberalization, following the failure of commercial banks to deliver
in rural areas. However, as prophesized by Diaz-Alejandro (1985), the end of
2006 and 2007 turned the financial sector in crisis as consequence of
unmonitored regularization, after which the central bank started exerting basic
controls on financial institutions through micro finance law and regulation
adopted in 2008, and strengthened by creation of MFI association created in
2007.
3.2.6 Monetary policy i n Rwanda
Monetary policy is a responsibility of the NBR and is a part
of the annual economic program aiming at implementing the medium-term program
referred to as EDPRS. Like all central banks, NBR uses open market operations,
reserve requirements (fixed at 8% before 2009 and reduced to 5% from 2009), and
discount rate (which fluctuates between 7.5 % and 8%). With its basic objective
of price and foreign exchange stability, its development can be regarded in two
periods: the period of financial regulation, from 1964 to 1995 and after
liberalization in 1995.
Before 1995, the country was in fixed exchange rate regime.
From 1970 to 1990, the foreign exchange rate was 1$ for nearly 82 RWF. However,
the war period 1990-1994 saw many devaluations, especially that of 1991 with
51.5 % and that of 1994 of 91.64% and by the end of 1994, the exchange rate
stood at 1$ for 220 RWF (DUSHIMUMUKIZA, 2006).
The period of flexible exchange rate was characterized by
volatility in exchange rate. As evidence, in January 2003, the average exchange
rate stood at 511.2168 RWF for 1$, but by end of the year, the exchange rate
was at 574.83RWF for 1$. The depreciation rate stood at 11.6% from one year to
another. If we compare the average exchange rate of 2002 and 2008, the index is
115.2 in six years, from the exchange rate of 475.32 FRW for 1$ in 2002 to
547.61 FRW for 1$ in 2008 (NBR, annual report, 2008). Indeed, this exchange
rate can be compared to 220 RWF for 1$ in 1994.
Regarding price stability, again the rampant inflation
characterized the after liberalization period, as compared to the period before
where the price stability was observed. Evidence from Kigali (the Capital city)
in 2003 shows that the CPI for all products in constant terms of 1982 was
559.32 compared to the CPI of 408.93 and in 1996 (NBR, annual report of 2003).
The inflation rate is fluctuating around 7.5%
For money supply, there was an upward trend in money supply
to the level where its growth rate was above that of GDP. For instance, in
2007, increase in money supply was 31.25% against 13% of nominal GDP. Indeed,
in some years, the money supply experiences an over expansion, especially
during election periods like 2003 and 2008.
For payment system monetization, SIMTEL was introduced in
2005 aiming at speeding up the level of financial innovation, which is very
low, as in 2008 the value of transactions using bank cards was 0.59 percent of
the non cash payment instruments (dominated by cheques) and cash payment
represented 98% of the payment system (NBR, 2009). Introduction of Real Time
Gross Settlement and an Automated Clearing House were few among mechanisms of
such modernization.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
3.3 Comparison of financial development within
EAC
The discussion omits comparison based on the number of
financial institutions as the countries are not equally sized and formal
financial markets since Rwanda and Burundi do not have them while Kenya
launched its stock market (Nairobi Stock Exchange) in 1954 and those of
Tanzania and Uganda are operational since 1998. We rather use some ratios
regarded as proxies of the level of financial development.
The need for this comparison lies in the sense that the
macroeconomic policies of these countries are tied together, hence it pays for
Rwanda to know its status quo in this community of countries. Three indicators
are used: Liquid liabilities as % of GDP, claims on private sector to GDP ratio
and domestic credit to GDP ratio. Data which are sources of the figures are
presented in appendices.
3.3.1 Ratio of Liquid liabilities (M3) to
GDP
Rwanda and Uganda are the last and their M3/GDP ratio are far
below the average of the AEC (21.98 % of GDP) with Kenya leading at 39.77%
compared to 15.35% of Rwanda, as shown by the chart below:
45
40
25
20
50
35
30
15
10
0
5
Rwanda Burundi Uganda Tanzania Kenya
Figure 1: Evolution i n ration of liquid liabilities i n
EAC
On overall, Kenya comes first followed by Tanzania, Burundi,
Rwanda and Uganda. We noted that in 2005, worldwide ranking of these countries
were: Kenya 94th, Tanzania 113rd, Burundi
118th, Rwanda 131st and Uganda 132nd out of
173 countries, with weighted average of 58%.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
3.3.2 Claims o n private sector to GDP ratio
This indictor was suggested by some researchers as the best
measurement of the level of financial depth as discussed in chapter two. The
figure below indicates the level of financial depth in East African Countries
had been this indicator used.
35
30
25
20
15
10
0
5
Rwanda Burundi Uganda Tanzania Kenya
Figure 2: Evolution i n average of claims o n private
sector to GDP i n EAC
Kenya is still leading followed by Burundi whereas other
countries are almost at the same level, which is very low below the average of
14.75%. Rwanda is the fourth with 7.05% while Uganda is the last in the group
with 6.11%. Based on this indicator, we can say that Kenya enjoys a financial
deepening four times that of Rwanda. However, Rwanda has been improving but at
a slow rate compared to Burundi which made a significant improvement. This
ratio for Burundi was more than three times that of Uganda and more than double
that of Rwanda in recent period, while 30 years ago the difference between
these countries was slightly small (less than 3%).
3.3.3 Domestic credit to GDP ratio
As the next figure shows, Burundi has been improving
considerably from the last in row during the period 1970-1975 (with 9.45 %) to
the 2nd position (with 36.62%) for last two consecutive periods,
from 1995 to 2005. Surprisingly, this indicator declined considerably in
Rwanda's post genocide where it moved from 17.51% as the average for the war
period of 1990-1995 to 11.54% for the last period 2001-2005 while the country
was supposed to be putting enough effort in the credit to private sector to
speed up the economic growth.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
45.00
40.00
50.00
35.00
30.00
25.00
20.00
15.00
10.00
0.00
5.00
Rwanda Burundi Uganda Tanzania Kenya
Figure 3: Evolution i n average ratio of domestic credit
to GDP i n EAC
This ratio for Rwanda was below the EAC average throughout
the period. Moreover, there is an increasing gap between Rwanda, the last in
group, and Kenya, the first, from 11.46% over the period 1970-1975 to 27.97%.
This is one among reasons that explain the gap in the level of economic
development among these countries. Uganda and Tanzania too have the low ratio.
Though several reasons can explain why Rwanda is lagging behind in financial
development, civil war, insecurity and poor governance are paramount factors to
the explanation. However, a detailed analysis is needed to explain why Tanzania
and Uganda are not performing well in some areas while they enjoyed a relative
stability, contrary to Burundi which was in war since 1993 up to 2005 and
performed well.
3.4 Co nclusio
Rwandan economy has been growing during post genocide period
but still the economy is at the lower level when compared to other countries.
Indeed, the financial development is still low and below the average of the
East African countries. When considering some indicators of the financial
development over the period 1970-2005, Rwanda is almost the last within five
countries though Uganda and Tanzania too are not performing well. This
observation brings to mind the empirical question of the extent to which the
level of financial development in Rwanda is linked with the level of economic
growth. Therefore the following chapter presents the methodology followed to
conduct this study.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
CHAPTER 4
METHODOLOGY
4.0 I ntroductio
This chapter presents the methods and techniques, the model,
estimation techniques and types of data used in this study in investigating the
causality among the proxies of financial development and economic growth.
4.1 Meaning and rationale of the model used
The use of VAR was motivated by its ability to capture the
dynamic interaction of financial sector development and economic growth. A VAR
is a direct generalization of the univariate AR(p) model to the case of a
vector of variables and is used to express the dynamic correlations between the
variables and hence is considered as an alternative to large-scale simultaneous
equations structural models (Brooks, 2008).
It allows treating each variable as endogenous thus avoiding
restrictions, judged incredible by Sims (1980), imposed by univariate AR, by
specifying some variables as being exogenous. This model was chosen because the
changes in indicators of financial development are possibly correlated with the
disturbance term in the equation of economic growth. This is because an
unobserved factor that influences growth of GDP may very well influence
indicators of financial development, making them endogenous. Further more, this
study joins other studies on the matter which used the VAR frame work, namely:
Hassan and Jung-Suk (2007); Teame (2002); Sakutukwa (2008) and others.
4.2 Model specification and rationale of
variables
In a VAR model, all variables have equations linking the
change in that variable to its own current and past values and the current and
past values of all the variables in the model, as it describes the dynamic
evolution of a number of variables from their common history (Verbeek, 2004).
The model is expressed
in a matrix form as:Yt = B +
Elic_i AtYt_i + Et with:
V, = ( GRATES
DEPTHBANKPRIVATESOPHT )
Yt : It is a 5×1 column vector of 5 variables
including proxy measures of the financial development, B is a 5×1 column
vector of constants, At and
Yt_i are
5×5 matrices of coefficients and lagged variables
respectively, i is the lag length
to be determined by AIC criteria and et is a 5×1
column vector of error terms. Variables included in the models are:
GRATE = Growth rate of Real per capita GDP, following the works
of Sinha and Macri (2001) and Kesseven et al (2007);
DEPTH = Claims on Private sector to GDP ratio considered as
proxy of financial deepening, following the works of Karima and Holden (2001),
Firdu and Struthers (2003) and Zhang et al (2007);
BANK = Domestic credit by deposit money bank and other banking
institutions divided by total domestic credit;
PRIVATE = Claims on the non-financial private sector to gross
domestic credit; SOPHT = Ratio of broad money to narrow money (M2/M1) as proxy
of financial sophistication, following the work of Sakutukwa (2008).
BANK and PRIVATE are inspired by the work of Levine and King
(1993). Unlike to them, we have included the domestic credit for other banking
institutions in BANK to mitigate the drawbacks of this indicator as commercial
banks are not the only financial institutions to provide valuable financial
functions. However, there is still a weakness in these proxies in Rwanda
because data used on assets of financial institutions do not include the UBPR
which play an important role in Rwandan financial sector.
4.3. Model estimatio
4.3.1 Statio narity and coi ntegratio
Due to spurious regression resulting from nonstationary
series in the regressions, we have conducted the tests for stationarity, using
ADF to check whether the residual series are white noise. The tests for
cointegration have been conducted to determine the form of the VAR to be
estimated. In fact, trend stationary variables are estimated by OLS, if the
variables contain stochastic trends and cointegrated, a VECM is used and
finally if the variables are not stationary and not cointegrated, the model is
estimated after the stochastic
trends have been removed by taking first differences of the data.
All tests were run within Eviews 6.
4.3.2 Granger causality tests
To determine which sets of variables have a significant
effects on each dependent variable, causality tests have been conducted by
restricting the coefficient of the lags of a particular variable to zero
(Wooldridge, 1990). The objective is to find out if changes in one variable do
affect changes in another variable and vice versa. If this is the case, as
explained by Brooks (2008), a sets of lags of the included variable should be
significant and it would be said that there is a bi-directional causality,
otherwise it should be said that some included variables are exogenous or no
causality exists at all between variables had been all lags insignificant.
4.3.3. Variance decomposition and Impulse
response
The ambiguity in interpreting individual coefficients in VAR
model (Gujarati, 2004) motivated us to use the variance decomposition and
impulse response function which trace out the response of the dependent
variable in the VAR model to shocks in the error term for several periods in
the future, keeping constant all other variables dated t and
before.
4.4. The data source and measurement
The five considered time series are ratios we have computed
from data provided by the IFS Yearbooks. The database includes 42 annual
observations from 1964 to 2005. Unlikely to previous studies which used natural
logarithm of the series, we did not find any graphical relationship, as advised
by Gujarati (2004), which motivates a priori transformation of the data to
log-log model.
4.5 Co nclusio
This chapter has presented the methodology that has been used
in this study. The next chapter presents and analyses the results of
econometric estimation. The main objective of the chapter is the hypothesis
testing.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
CHAPTER 5
MODEL ESTIMATION AND FINDINGS
5.0 I ntroductio
So far we have presented the literature both on theoretical
and empirical side on the causality between economic growth and financial
development. It is now time to turn to the empirical testing of this
relationship for Rwandan economy. This chapter presents the results obtained
from econometric testing and discusses the meaning and reason behind the
figures.
5.1 Test for statio narity
The footstep of this analysis is to determine whether the
series are stationary or not. The ADF was used to test for stationarity of
these series as it provides a superior test to DF, especially in case the
residuals of the regression could be serially correlated. The lag length has
been automatically selected by AIC from nine proposed lags and all three
possibilities have been tested: neither intercept nor trend, intercept but no
trend and both intercept and trend. In all cases, results were found similar
irrespective of the model used.
Here we present the results from the general model including
intercept with
trend, as depicted by: AYt=f3i +
f32t + SYt_i + al El:=i AYt_p + Et.
In addition, we have tested for the presence of trend in series,
with the model:
Yt =cx +f3t + Et. The presence or the absence of the trend will
be used for
subsequent tests. The table below presents the results:
Table 2: ADF Test Statistics i n levels
Variable
|
t= statistics
|
Critical values at
|
Lag length
|
Decision at 5%
|
|
5%
|
|
Presence of trend
|
GRATE
|
-3.59
|
-4.20
|
-3.52
|
1
|
Stationary
|
No
|
DEPTH
|
-6.11
|
-2.62
|
-1.94
|
0
|
Stationary
|
Yes
|
|
Variable
|
t= statistics
|
Critical values at
|
Lag length
|
Decision at 5%
|
|
5%
|
|
Presence of trend
|
SOPHT
|
-3.36
|
-4.21
|
-3.52
|
2
|
Not stationary
|
Yes
|
BANK
|
-2.96
|
-4.19
|
-3.52
|
0
|
Not stationary
|
Yes
|
PRIVATE
|
-2.25
|
-4.21
|
-3.55
|
3
|
Stationary
|
Yes
|
|
The hypotheses tested are:
Ho: S = 0, the series are not stationary, )62 = 0,
there is no trend
Ho: S * 0, the series are stationary, )62 * 0, there
is a trend
After taking first differences of SOPHT and BANK, the series
were found to be stationary at 1%, as the table below depicts:
Table 3: ADF Test Statistics with first
difference
Variables
|
t=
|
Critical values at
|
Lag length
|
Decision
|
|
Statistic
|
1%
|
5%
|
selected
|
|
D(SOPHT)
|
-6.019
|
-4.205
|
-3.526
|
0
|
Stationary at 1%
|
D(BANK)
|
-6.759
|
-4.211
|
-3.529
|
1
|
Stationary at 1%
|
|
The above results conclude that GRATE, DEPTH and PRIVATE are
I(0) while SOPHT and BANK are I(1). Therefore, VAR in levels cannot be
applied.
5.2 Test for coi ntegratio
In econometric literature, it is not clear whether
cointegration should be applied to only series integrated of the same order.
Though Verbeck (2004) noted that the concept of cointegration can be applied to
(nonstationary) integrated time series only and Dickey et al, quoted by
Gujarati (2004), stipulated that Cointegration deals with the relationship
among a group of variables, where (unconditionally) each has a unit root,
however Brooks (2004) stressed that it is also possible to combine levels and
first differenced terms in a VECM. The later therefore illustrates that
cointegration can exist among variables not integrated of the same order.
Heij et al (2004) developed the mathematical proof of this
view where they asserted that a cointegration relationship exists between
stationary and nonstationary variables. If their mathematical proof is put in
simple terms, there are three possibilities in VAR with many variables: If m:
the number of variables, r= rank of the matrix of coefficients and also the
number of cointegration relations, therefore:
· If all variables are stationary, r=m and all roots lie
outside the unit cycle
· If all variables are not stationary, r=0, there are m
unit roots or m stochastic trends.
· If some variables are stationary and others not
stationary, r= 0<r<m, there are m-r unit roots, the polynomial have m-r
common stochastic trends and there are r cointegrating relations.
As some variables are stationary and others not, Johansen
cointegration test has been used to determine whether there exists a long-run
relationship between these variables. This test was preferred to Engle-Granger
approach because in case of five variables we may have more than one
cointegrating relationship (Brooks, 2004).
a) Johansen coi ntegratio n test
Johansen trace test was used on the number of cointegrating
relations with null hypothesis of no cointegration between series against the
alternative hypothesis of existence of cointegration between the series. All
variables enter the cointegration analysis in levels. This table depicts
cointegrating vectors for each model with 4 lags.
Table 4: Number of coi ntegrati ng relations by model, at
5% level*
Data Trend:
|
None
|
None
|
Linear
|
Linear
|
Quadratic
|
Test Type
|
No Intercept
|
Intercept
|
Intercept
|
Intercept
|
Intercept
|
|
No Trend
|
No Trend
|
No Trend
|
Trend
|
Trend
|
Trace
|
2
|
3
|
3
|
4
|
3
|
Max-Eig
|
0
|
1
|
3
|
4
|
3
|
*Critical values based on MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999)
All five possibilities about the nature of deterministic trend
assumption suggest that the series are cointegrated. At least there is one
cointegrating factor except the Max-Eig method with neither intercept nor
trend in data, which is unlikely to
be the case. The subsequent step is to determine whether an
intercept or trend or both are included in the cointegrating relationship and
to present the results of the selected model. The analysis of the nature of
trend conducted showed that all variables except GRATE have significant
intercept and trend. After estimating the selected model of both intercept and
trend with 3 lags selected by AIC, the results were as follows:
Table 5: Unrestricted Coi ntegrati ng Rank Test
(Trace)
Hypothesized No. of CE(s)
|
Eigenvalue
|
Trace Statistic
|
0.05 Critical Value
|
Prob.**
|
None *
|
0.890720
|
137.1029
|
88.80380
|
0.0000
|
At most 1
|
0.517635
|
55.19081
|
63.87610
|
0.2162
|
At most 2
|
0.306696
|
28.21578
|
42.91525
|
0.6091
|
At most 3
|
0.251814
|
14.66319
|
25.87211
|
0.6026
|
At most 4
|
0.100754
|
3.929364
|
12.51798
|
0.7523
|
Trace test indicates 1 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level *
denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis
(1999) p-values
The statistic of 137.1 considerably exceeds the critical value
(of 88.8) and so the null of no cointegrating vectors is rejected. But the
2nd row shows that the null hypothesis of at most one cointegrating
vector can not be rejected as trace statistic of 55.19 is less than critical
value of 63.9. Therefore, there exists one cointegrating relation which means
that the rank of the matrix (r) is one.
The results from trace test were the same if maximum
eigenvalue test was considered. As there is one cointegrating vector, this
allows us to estimate a VECM, in line with advice of Brooks (2004) of not using
models in differences when cointegration is present, as this flows away
important information and have no long-run solution.
5.3 Vector Error Correction Model (VECM)
The lag length was chosen based on AIC, which was consistent
with LR and HQ. Noting that as data are annual observations, a maximum of 4
lags is reasonable, as suggested by Brooks (2004) based on the frequency of the
observation and AIC picked 3 lags. The estimated output is presented in the
appendix, but the table below presents the significant lags at 5% level.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Table 6: Significant Vector Error Correction
Estimates
Variable
|
Significant lags at 5% and their coefficients i n I
l
|
D(GRATE)
|
CointEq1
[-2.03]
|
D(GRATE(-1)) [0.63]
|
D(GRATE(-2)) [0.25)
|
D(DEPTH(-1)) [0.69]
|
D(DEPTH(-2)) [0.86]
|
D(DEPTH(-3)) [0.96]
|
D(Bank(-1)) [0.4]
|
|
D(DEPTH)
|
CointEq1
[-1.16]
|
D(DEPHT(-1)) [0.69]
|
D(DEPTH(-2)) [-0.79]
|
D(DEPTH(-3)) [-0.49]
|
D(SOPHT(-1) [1.01]
|
|
|
|
D(SOPHT)
|
CointEq1
[-0.72]
|
D(PRIVATE(-2)) [-0.7]
|
|
|
D(BANK)
|
D(Bank(-1))
[-0.51]
|
D(PRIVATE(-1)) [1.11]
|
D(PRIVATE(-2)) [-1.26]
|
D(PRIVATE(-3)) [0.95]
|
D(PRIVATE)
|
D(PRIVATE(-1)) [0.62]
|
D(PRIVATE(-2)) [-0.52]
|
D(PRIVATE(-3)) [0.48]
|
|
The Error correction term showing the long-run equilibrium is
estimated as:
CointEgl = GRATEt_i -- 0.057 SOPHTt_i + 0.0019 /31t -- 0.0019
/30
+ 0.332DEPHTt_1 -- 0.114 PRIVATEt_i + 0.298BANKt_1
In all equations, the cointegrating equation has a negative
sign as expected and significant in three out of five equations. We note from
the table above that in many equations of the VECM, the coefficients of lags of
other variables are not significant, especially for PRIVATE which is determined
solely by its own lags, SOPHT is explained by one lag from PRIVATE whereas for
DEPTH only its own lags and 1 lag of SOPHT are significant.
The cointegration is strongly significant for GRATE, DEPTH and
SOPHT. However, as noted by Brooks (2004), evaluation of the significance of
variables in a VECM is based on the joint tests on all of the lags of a
variable in the equation rather than individual coefficient estimates.
Therefore we proceed to F test as indicated in the table below:
Table 7: F=statistics for VECM
Variables
|
D(GRATE)
|
D(DEPTH)
|
D(SOPHT)
|
D(Bank)
|
D(Private)
|
R2
|
0.97
|
0.67
|
0.67
|
0.62
|
0.55
|
Adj R2
|
0.95
|
0.41
|
0.41
|
0.33
|
0.19
|
F-stat
|
45.41
|
2.59
|
2.60
|
2.12
|
1.54
|
Critical values of F-statistic are taken from F-statistic table
provided by Gujarati (2004) and are 3.09; 2.2 and 1.84 for 1%; 5% and 10%
respectively. The VECM
shows that for GRATE the null hypothesis being all
coefficients are simultaneously zero is rejected at 1%, for DEPTH and SOPHT the
null hypothesis is rejected at 5%, for BANK it is rejected at 10% and for
PRIVATE the null hypothesis can not be definitely rejected.
The results suggest that there exist: a long-run relationship
between growth rate of real per capita GDP and proxies of financial
development, a long-run relationship between financial depth, rate of growth of
real per capita GDP and other included measures of financial development and
the same applies to financial sophistication. The F-test denies any long-run
relationship between the ratio of credit to private sector to total domestic
credit with GDP, and other measures of financial development and for the ratio
of credit allocated by banks to total domestic credit when 5% level is
considered.
5.4 The E ngle=Gra nger test
The test is meant to detect any short-term relationship
between the variables and it is applied to test whether the changes in one
variable can cause changes in another variable and vice-versa. As there is a
long-run relationship between variables, the error correction term will be
included in the Granger causality test for estimating a short-run relationship.
It is worth noting that Granger causality test should be applied to stationary
series (Sinha and Macri, 2001). Therefore, we have applied this test with
differences in non-stationary series. When estimated the VAR model with
differences in nonstationary variables to come up with lag length, the AIC and
HQ criteria gave out 5 lags. The model to be estimated is:
M'at =0(0-Foci ~ 78 ~ ~~ ~ 98 ~
8 8 ~~ where Ya and Yb are
~~~ ~~~
variables on which causality test is being applied. The
hypotheses to be tested are:
Ho: âi=0, Yb does not Granger causes Ya
H1: âi ?0, Yb does Granger causes Ya
The results for Granger causality are presented in table
below:
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Table 8: Marginal significance levels associated with
joint F=test
Dependent variable
|
Lags of variables
|
Significant lags
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
DSOPHT
|
DBANK
|
PRIVATE
|
GRATE
|
0
|
9.8E-13
|
0.01503
|
0.60738
|
0.16923
|
DEPTH and SOPHT
|
DEPTH
|
0.99980
|
0
|
0.12400
|
0.99071
|
0.61635
|
None
|
DSOPT
|
0.00777
|
0.00338
|
0
|
0.54904
|
0.28578
|
GRATE and DEPTH
|
DBANK
|
0.99662
|
0.08847
|
0.73048
|
0
|
0.03597
|
PRIVATE
|
PRIVATE
|
0.25647
|
0.29164
|
0.38541
|
0.82127
|
0
|
None
|
The table above gives the probability values at 5% for the
null hypothesis that all the lags of a given variable are jointly insignificant
in a given equation. The second row after the headings shows that all the lags
of DEPTH and DSOPHT are jointly significant in explaining the changes of GRATE
(values less than 0.05). Indeed, both lags of GRATE and DEPTH jointly explain
the changes in DSOPHT. Moreover, a part from the lags of PRIVATE which jointly
explain DBANK, there is as well no causality between DEPTH and other variables
as applied for PRIVATE.
The Engle-Granger causality suggests that in short-term, there
is unidirectional causality from financial deepening to growth rate of real per
capita GDP and bidirectional feedback between financial sophistication and
growth rate of real per capita GDP. But other proxies of financial development
do not seem to have affected economic growth, or being affected by economic
growth.
5.5 Impulse responses and variance
decompositions
The Granger Causality solves the problem of existence or not
of variables with significant lags in the model but will not indicate whether
there is a positive or a negative relationship between variables or how long
the effects will take place. Fortunately, this information is given by Variance
decomposition and Impulse responses.
5.5.1 Variance decompositio
Gebhard and Wolters (2007) define variance decompositions as a
determinant of how much the s-step-ahead forecast error variance of a given
variable is
explained by innovations to each explanatory variable for s = 1,
2, etc. The estimated variance decompositions are as follows:
Table 9: Variance decomposition of GRATE
Period
|
S.E.
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.110866
|
100.0000
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
2
|
0.124707
|
82.69667
|
8.579287
|
3.272943
|
3.121836
|
2.329268
|
3
|
0.147683
|
68.46577
|
21.21998
|
2.911180
|
3.706309
|
3.696768
|
4
|
0.161082
|
63.06704
|
22.01977
|
5.362547
|
4.577584
|
4.973060
|
5
|
0.230705
|
30.74644
|
56.71985
|
2.944156
|
5.417225
|
4.172328
|
6
|
0.264102
|
25.86977
|
48.00195
|
11.86883
|
10.10530
|
4.154157
|
7
|
0.279128
|
27.88629
|
45.35033
|
11.21903
|
9.305821
|
6.238536
|
8
|
0.297045
|
24.98740
|
40.23873
|
20.10273
|
9.132219
|
5.538915
|
9
|
0.299774
|
25.47580
|
39.51314
|
20.12288
|
9.053579
|
5.834607
|
10
|
0.311132
|
25.82532
|
38.50044
|
21.06230
|
8.824819
|
5.787122
|
The data shows that in period 1, changes in Growth rate of GDP
are due to its own shocks at 100%. However as time passes, the effects of
shocks of other proxies of financial development to GDP increase significantly,
especially financial depth shocks, which increase from 0 in period 1 to 56% in
fifth period and represent more than 45% of all shocks on GDP from period 5-7
and nearly 40% above period 8. For Financial sophistication, although its
shocks to GDP are low up to fifth period, they become important in the
long-run, as they account from 10% - 20% of the whole shocks in GDP growth
rate.
In long-run, BANK and PRIVATE exert some influence on Growth
rate of GDP as they account for around 9% and 6 % respectively after the
seventh period. This leads to a considerable decrease of responsiveness of
growth rate of GDP to its own shocks from the range of 20% to 30 % after the
fifth period.
Table 10: Variance decomposition of DEPTH
Period
|
S.E.
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.166228
|
6.593561
|
93.40644
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
2
|
0.177693
|
5.794367
|
81.81403
|
10.71161
|
1.676598
|
0.003399
|
3
|
0.181328
|
6.251779
|
78.93336
|
11.59888
|
3.148914
|
0.067069
|
4
|
0.196067
|
5.909571
|
67.51985
|
21.31578
|
3.279901
|
1.974900
|
5
|
0.200638
|
5.771625
|
64.94746
|
20.47421
|
6.396104
|
2.410596
|
6
|
0.203363
|
5.642555
|
63.22212
|
20.70156
|
7.800917
|
2.632850
|
7
|
0.204559
|
5.698593
|
62.48965
|
20.49198
|
8.642176
|
2.677599
|
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Period S.E. GRATE DEPTH SOPHT BANK PRIVATE
8
|
0.206029
|
5.618773
|
61.74162
|
20.20135
|
9.476386
|
2.961867
|
9
|
0.206866
|
5.583026
|
61.38685
|
20.08648
|
9.998728
|
2.944921
|
10
|
0.209391
|
5.449760
|
61.67798
|
19.73869
|
10.25844
|
2.875138
|
From the first period, the shocks in GDP growth rate account
for 6.59% of the shocks in DEPTH and no other variable exerts a shock on
financial depth. However, as from the fourth period, the financial
sophistication exerts a relatively higher significant influence on DEPTH than
other variables, around 20%. Shocks in rate of GDP account still for around 5%
and 2.8% for PRIVATE. It is noted that the impact of BANK shocks as well
increase in the long-run, from 0% to 10.25% from the first period onwards.
Table 11: Variance decomposition of SOPHT
Period
|
S.E.
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.074312
|
26.69308
|
0.003523
|
73.30339
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
2
|
0.092146
|
18.38277
|
0.672448
|
74.86819
|
6.069340
|
0.007246
|
3
|
0.133858
|
9.698140
|
11.79599
|
67.75000
|
7.847544
|
2.908331
|
4
|
0.170257
|
6.012045
|
23.10979
|
54.15415
|
12.49342
|
4.230598
|
5
|
0.220413
|
3.774206
|
39.20184
|
37.55349
|
15.89273
|
3.577740
|
6
|
0.240093
|
3.239503
|
40.45313
|
31.95285
|
20.92763
|
3.426890
|
7
|
0.258410
|
2.844621
|
43.07799
|
28.56225
|
21.77780
|
3.737332
|
8
|
0.271110
|
2.841146
|
44.52708
|
26.18426
|
22.98927
|
3.458246
|
9
|
0.279182
|
2.780299
|
45.79558
|
24.69353
|
23.46618
|
3.264411
|
10
|
0.284385
|
2.707705
|
46.31954
|
23.86455
|
23.96186
|
3.146348
|
From the above table, the shocks in growth rate of GDP account
for 26.69% in explaining changes in financial sophistication whereas its own
shocks account for 73%, as other variables do not influence SOPHT in the first
period. However, this order changes over time as financial depth takes over
growth rate of GDP in explaining changes in financial sophistication. In fact,
starting from the third period, shocks in financial depth lead to variability
in financial sophistication by 11.7% compared to 9.6% of growth rate in GDP
where still its own shocks account for more than 60%.
The influence of financial depth increases considerably up to
40% in sixth period and the own shocks decline to 31.95%, coupled with an
increase in influence of BANK with 20.92% and a decrease in influence of GDP
rate from 26.69% to 3.23% and remained at this level. The impact of PRIVATE
shocks
remains low close to 3.5% whereas that of shocks from
financial depth account for 40% to 45% in long-run, leaving the own shocks
between 30% to 23% and BANK shocks around 23%.
Table 12: Variance decomposition of BANK
Period
|
S.E.
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.108855
|
0.758292
|
7.481317
|
2.693772
|
89.06662
|
0.000000
|
2
|
0.134533
|
2.800047
|
9.892457
|
3.375928
|
70.39165
|
13.53991
|
3
|
0.157558
|
3.654779
|
15.77366
|
3.449549
|
66.83704
|
10.28497
|
4
|
0.179687
|
4.319090
|
21.15028
|
5.165073
|
61.43189
|
7.933671
|
5
|
0.210744
|
5.307566
|
19.52585
|
10.44650
|
54.85325
|
9.866828
|
6
|
0.238217
|
5.969085
|
17.27681
|
17.65179
|
48.14008
|
10.96223
|
7
|
0.252272
|
6.237416
|
17.76269
|
20.31924
|
45.59069
|
10.08995
|
8
|
0.269294
|
6.611854
|
17.00039
|
23.16878
|
43.29296
|
9.926012
|
9
|
0.288331
|
6.654749
|
15.18331
|
25.94057
|
40.74650
|
11.47487
|
10
|
0.301548
|
6.780441
|
14.72203
|
27.67418
|
39.01775
|
11.80560
|
The part of changes to BANK due to its own shocks declines
sharply from 89% in the first period to around 40% in long-run. In the
short-run, shocks from DEPTH have a largest impact on BANK, varying from 7% to
21% whereas in long-run, shocks from SOPHT outweigh DEPTH shocks in explaining
changes in BANK. Financial deepening and sophistication continue to exert a
significant influence on the ratio of sources of credit (BANK), contributing to
40% of BANK shocks in the long-run (from the fifth period). Whereas, the shocks
from growth rate of GDP and PRIVATE account for nearly 6% and 10%
respectively.
Table 13: Variance decomposition of PRIVATE
Period
|
S.E.
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.058234
|
3.888004
|
8.796400
|
31.81067
|
0.011581
|
55.49335
|
2
|
0.113552
|
7.271370
|
4.966717
|
42.35623
|
0.397619
|
45.00806
|
3
|
0.147942
|
7.691150
|
8.030448
|
46.93222
|
1.178470
|
36.16772
|
4
|
0.185169
|
7.908759
|
8.726697
|
52.17925
|
0.932194
|
30.25310
|
5
|
0.228011
|
8.044798
|
8.260887
|
54.36709
|
0.645529
|
28.68169
|
6
|
0.267550
|
7.654312
|
6.582612
|
58.03725
|
0.605966
|
27.11986
|
7
|
0.295786
|
7.572517
|
6.240606
|
59.76170
|
0.888040
|
25.53714
|
8
|
0.325691
|
7.389561
|
5.409754
|
61.44629
|
0.957495
|
24.79690
|
9
|
0.352531
|
7.122818
|
4.661823
|
61.92543
|
1.102570
|
25.18736
|
10
|
0.376020
|
6.932724
|
4.193691
|
62.39958
|
1.343631
|
25.13037
|
Compared to other variables mentioned above, PRIVATE own shocks
are relatively small (55.5%) in the first period, and the shocks decline
sharply to a
quarter in long-run. Shocks from Financial sophistication have
a strong influence on PRIVATE and account for more than a half of total shocks
from the fourth period onwards. Shocks from BANK are insignificants as they do
not account for 2% and shocks from growth rate of GDP and DEPTH together
account for nearly 10% of total PRIVATE shocks.
5.5.2 Impulse response models
Gebhard and Wolters (2007) define impulse responses as the
measure of the effect of a unit shock of the variable i at time t on the
variable j in later periods. So for each variable from each equation
separately, a unit shock is applied to the error term and the effects upon the
VAR system over time are noted. Details of impulse responses are presented in
appendices and their summarized results are:
o Positive shocks of DEPTH and BANK to GDP growth rate but
negative shocks from SOPHT and PRIVATE.
o Positive shocks on DEPTH from GDP growth rate, financial
sophistication and BANK in short-run. Moreover, SOPHT and BANK have positive
shocks on DEPTH in long-run and negative PRIVATE shocks on DEPTH.
o Positive shocks on financial sophistication from BANK and
growth rate of GDP in short-run and negative shocks from growth rate of GDP,
DEPTH and PRIVATE in long-run.
o Positive shocks on BANK from PRIVATE and negative shocks from
growth rate of GDP and financial sophistication.
o Negative shocks on PRIVATE from all variables.
In the results above, the ordering was GRATE, DEPTH, SOPHT,
BANK, and PRIVATE. Unfortunately, the main drawback of Variance decomposition
and Impulse responses is that if the variable order is altered the results will
change too. For independent results from variable order, a priori knowledge
about the order is required, but not easy in most interdependent financial time
series data.
5.6 Discussion of findings
The tests revealed a long-run relationship between the Growth
rate of real per capita GDP and 4 proxies of financial development.
Precisely, financial
deepening and financial sophistication were revealed to be
associated to this rate of GDP in the long-run. This implies that as the
economy allocates more credit to the private sector, as new financial
instruments are introduced in Rwandan financial system, with time, then the
level of economic growth will be affected. The causality test, Variance
decomposition and impulse responses show that financial deepening influences
positively economic growth. But no bidirectional causality detected from growth
rate of GDP to financial deepening.
These results confirm the importance of the level of financial
depth for Rwandan economic growth, unlikely to the conclusion of some
researchers who used panel data analysis and affirmed the irrelevance of the
level of financial deepening on economic growth for Sub-Saharan Africa and poor
countries in general, as noted by Hassan and Jung-Suk (2007) and Michael and
Giovanni (2001). Our results do agree with the conclusions of Zhang et al
(2007) in China, Demetriades and Luintel (1996) in India and Sakutukwa (2008)
in Zimbabwe.
The causality test and variance decomposition showed a
bi-directional influence between the level of financial sophistication and
economic growth. Surprisingly, impulse responses show that this relationship is
negative and a mere interpretation may conclude that financial sophistication
aggravates economic growth. But there can be an intuitive explanation of this
situation: «the true measurement of the financial sophistication in
Rwanda». The used growth rate of real per capita GDP excludes effects of
inflation and the increase in the ratio of M2 to M1 used as proxy of financial
sophistication could imply increase in money supply due to inflationary
pressure rather than financial innovation.
This is the case for Rwanda where post genocide economy was
characterized by high rate of inflation and volatility in exchange rate.
Despite the increase in the quasi-money which resulted in the increase of the
ratio of M2 to M1, there was no E-banking in Rwanda up to 2005, no remarkable
new financial instruments and ATM cards were recent in few banks, in major
towns only.
No link was found between economic growth and allocation of
credit. Were the relationships to be established by Granger causality, the
impulse responses
show that the relationship would be negative. The absence or a
negative relationship between the growth rate of real per capita GDP and
PRIVATE, and between PRIVATE and DEPTH can be explained by the allocation of
credit. Credit devoted to agricultural sector which employs more than 80% of
the population was less than 1.5% of total credit to private sector while the
manufacturing, trade, restaurants and hotels received more than 60% of the
total credit, while these sectors employ less than 5% of the population and
contributed to only 17.4% in GDP in 2005.
Moreover, some loans were given to no profitable projects and
non credit worthy customers as indicated by the high level of defaulters which
led to bank crisis in former BACAR, BICDI and many MFIs. These findings of
negative relationship between credit allocation and economic growth conquer
with findings of Karima and Holden (2001), in a panel of 30 developing
countries.
5.7 Co nclusio
The study finds a strong positive causality from financial
deepening to economic growth and a negative bi-directional feedback between
economic growth and financial sophistication, in the short-run, and a long-run
relationship between economic growth and proxies of financial development.
The lack of short-run relationship between economic growth and
the credit allocation, from the source (commercial bank versus central bank) to
the users (private sector versus public sector) has been confirmed, while in
the long-run, variance decompositions and impulse responses showed a minor
relationship between economic growth rate and credit allocation. The found
negative link between level of economic growth and financial sophistication is
explained by the lack of accuracy of measurement of financial sophistication in
Rwanda. The next chapter will therefore put forward the general conclusions and
recommendations of the study.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
CHAPTER 6
CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
6.0 I ntroductio
This study intended to examine the bi-directional influence
between financial development and economic growth in Rwanda from 1964 to 2005.
Chapter one presented the existing problem which was the rationale of our study
alongside the objectives, research hypotheses among others. Chapter two
reviewed the literature on the subject both on theoretical and empirical
ground. In chapter three, a comparative analysis of the level of financial
development within East African countries has been carried out and revealed a
weak level of financial development in Rwanda. The results indicate that Rwanda
either takes the fourth or the last position among five countries.
In chapter four, we have explained the methodology followed,
focused on a VAR with five variables, namely: the indicator of financial
deepening, financial sophistication and other two indicators of the credit
allocation, and the growth rate of real per capita GDP was used as proxy of
economic growth. The fifth chapter has been devoted to econometric testing.
This chapter summarizes the results of the study and gives recommendations as
well as areas for further studies.
6.1 Summary of findings
The empirical results demonstrated both a short and a long-run
relationship between both financial depth and sophistication and economic
growth. For financial deepening, the causality runs from financial deepening to
economic growth and for financial sophistication, the causality is
bi-directional but negative. As some studies have concluded, we have not found
any evidence of the link between credit allocation and economic growth and even
if the relationship was to be significant, it would be negative. This is
explained by the pattern of the credit to private sector which has become
increasingly skewed to service sector with less employment and loan defaulters
rather than to agriculture and businesses for productive investments.
All in all, we found that the level of financial development
matters most for Rwandan economy, contrary to the irrelevance of the financial
development on economic growth in cross-sectional analysis for developing
countries confirmed by previous studies. The reason being that their analysis
does not take into consideration country's unique characteristics or the
results are biased by the presence of outliers in their regression, due to size
inequalities of countries within a region.
The first and fourth hypotheses were partly confirmed while
the second and third could not be confirmed. The study has attained its
objectives and recommendations for further strengthening both Rwandan financial
sector and Rwandan economy in general have been suggested.
6.2 Policy recommendations
Based on the results of the study, it is urgent that Rwandan
government takes the financial sector as a pillar of economic growth which can
replace non performing industrial sector and agriculture. The emphasis put on
it can allow Rwanda to be the net exporter of financial services within East
African Community and Commonwealth where Rwanda was admitted recently, as we do
not have any comparative advantage in remaining sectors.
The emphasis should be put on the level of financial
intermediation through increase in the credit allocated to private sector. It
is however important to note that the allocation of the credit should be
changed from private consumption and services to agriculture and other
investment projects like construction sector. Additionally, credit allocation
should be based on the profitability of the investment rather than personal
considerations or values.
More so, Rwandan government should accelerate financial
innovations which are currently very low, by making compulsory: distribution of
ATM cards by banks upon bank account opening; and the use of credit cards as a
means of payment in strong legalized supermarkets and shops, as a first step in
the introduction of card-based system of payment.
BPR S.A has provided evidence that bank branch proximity is a
key factor in bank profitability. It is therefore, recommended that other
commercial banks in Rwanda should open at least one branch in each district.
Due to the absence of positive impact of financial innovations on economic
growth explained by inflationary pressures and exchange rate depreciation, the
Government of Rwanda should put more efforts on price and exchange rate
stability.
The introduction of OTC market was a good step for financial
development. However, a lot need to be done regarding empowering the saving
capacity of Rwandans, by policy measures enhancing an equal distribution of
income, poverty eradication and the fight against rampant unemployment. We
believe these factors to have been the reasons for the absence of transactions
on OTC market rather than lack of public awareness as reported by
newspapers.
For employed population, the government of Rwanda should
ensure that the salary is enough to cover the subsistence needs so that saving
is possible. This can be done through the minimum wage legislation since a
larger group of employed people earn even what is not enough for family
expenses. In such conditions, any policy aimed at saving mobilization would
futile.
We can not claim that the study has explored all areas of the
problem. For instance, we have not used the level of stock market development
in our econometric analysis due to lack of data as the existing OTC started in
2008.
6.3 Areas for further research
Studies need to be conducted to determine best proxies of
financial development in Rwanda, especially for financial innovations, as the
used ratio of M2 to M1 may reflect the increase in classical saving functions
rather than diversification of financial instruments and use of modern
technology in the financial sector. Indeed, a cross-sectional study in EAC
would be interesting, to assess how developed financial systems are and how
they are relevant to economic growth.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
REFERENCES
1. Abebe, A. (1990), «Financial Repression and its
Impact on Financial development and Economic Growth in the African Least
Developed Countries", Savings and Development, no1, X1V, pp. 23-55.
2. Alison, T., Geda, A., Le Billon, P., Murshed, S.M. (2001),
«Financial Reconstruction in Conflict and 'Post-Conflict'
Economies", Paper presented at the Conference of the Finance and
Development Research Programme, pp. 5-6.
3. Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (2006),
«Financing Patterns around the World: Are Small Firms
Different?", World Bank mimeo.
4. Bodie. Z, Kane A. and Marcus A. (2008), Essentials of
Investments, McGraw -Hill International ed, 7ed, New York, USA
5. Brooks, C.(2008), "Introductory Econometrics for
Finance", 2nd ed, The ICMA Centre, University of Reading,
Cambridge University Press
6. Buffie, E. F. (1984), «Financial Repression: The
New Structuralist and Stabilization, Policy in Semi-industrialized
economies", Journal of Economic Development, 14,3, pp. 303-322.
7. Cameron, R. (1961), «France and Economic Development
in Europe", Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
8. CIA World Factbooks, 2003-2008,
www.cia.gov
9. CMAC, www,
cmac.gov.rw
10. Demetriades, P.O and Luintel, K.B (1996),
«Financial Development, Economic Growth and Banking Sector Controls:
Evidence from India", The Economic Journal, The Journal of the Royal
Economic Society, pp. 359- 374.
11. Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (1998),
«Law, Finance, and Firm Growth", Journal of Finance 53,
pp. 2107-2137.
12. Diaz-Alejandro, C.(1985), «Good-bye Financial
Repression, Hello Financial Crisis", Journal of Development Economics, 19
(1/2), 1-24.
13. Douglas, K. (2003), «The Finance Growth Nexus:
Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa", IAER: May 2003, Vol. 9, no. 2.
14. Dushimumukiza, D. (2006), «Correlation entre le Taux de
Change et la Balance des Paiements», UNR, Huye-Rwanda, Unpublished
Dissertation.
15.
Firdu, G. and Struthers, J. (2003), «The
McKinnon-Shaw Hypothesis: Thirty Years on: A Review of Recent Developments in
Financial Liberalization Theory", Paper presented at DSA Annual Conference
on «Globalisation and Development», Glasgow, Scotland, September
2003.
16. Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A.J. (1963), «A Monetary
History of United States, Princeton», Princeton University press
17. Fry, M.J. (1989), «Financial development: Theories
and recent experience", Oxford Review of Economic policy, vol 5 no 4
18. Fry, M.J. (1997), «In Favour of Financial
liberalization", The Economic Journal, Vol. 107, No. 442, pp.754-770.
19. Gebhard, K. and Wolters, J.(2007), «Introduction to
Modern Time series", Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg.
20. Greenwood, J. and Jovanovic, B. (1990), «Financial
Development and the Development of Income"; Journal of political economy,
Vol. 98
21. Gujarati, D. (2004), «Basic Econometrics",
4th edition, The MacGraw-Hill companies.
22. Habyalimana, S. (2007), «Access to Finance
Through Value 0hains: Lessons From Rwanda", AEGIS European Conference on
African Studies 11-14 July 2007, Leiden, the Netherlands.
23. Hassan, M. K. and Jung-Suk Y. (2007), «Financial
Development and Economic Growth: New Evidence from Panel Data", Journal of
Economic Literature, G21.
24. Heij, C, Paul, B, Philip, H.F, Kloek, T and Herman, K.V.
(2004), «Econometric Methods with application in Business and
Economics", Oxford University Press Inc., New York.
25. IFAD,
www.ifad.org
26. IMF (1994 and 2005), «International Financial
Statistics Yearbooks", Vol XLVII and Vol LVIII, Washington, D.0
27. IMF(2009), «World Economic Outlook Database",
April 2009 and October 2009
28. Jankee, K. (2006), «Banking Controls, Financial
deepening and Economic Growth in Mauritius", African Review of Money,
Finance and Banking, pp. 77-98.
29. Kantengwa. A, (2009), «Financial Cooperatives in
Rwanda: Historical Background and Regulation", Kigali, Rwanda.
30. Karima, S. and Holden, K. (2001), «Does Financial
Development affect Growth?", Liverpool John Moores University, UK
31. Kesseven, P., Boopen, S. and Ramesh, D. (2007),
«Financial Development and Economic Growth in Africa: a Dynamic Panel
Data Analysis", International Journal of Business Research.
32. Koðar, C.I (1995), «Financial Innovations
and Monetary Control", The Central Bank Of The Republic Of Turkey,
Research Department, Discussion Paper No: 9515
33. Kuznets, S. (1955), «Economic Growth and Income
Inequalities", An American economic review, Vol. 45
34. Levine, R. (1997), «Financial development and
economic growth: Views and Agenda», Journal of economic Literature
XXXV, pp. 688-726.
35. Levine, R. (2001), « Stock Market, Growth and Tax
Policy", Journal of finance, Vol. 46, no.4
36. Levine, R. and King, R.G. (1993), "Financial
Entrepreneurship and Growth. Theory and Evidence", Journal of Monetary
Economic.
37. Levine, R. and Zervos, S. (1996), "Stock markets, Banks
and Economic Growth", World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No 1690
38. Liu, L., Yunhua, B. Fleisher, Hongyi Li, (1994),
«Financial Intermediation, Inflation and Capital Formation in Rural
China", China Economic Review.
39. Loayza N., K. Schmidt-Hebbel, and L. Serven (2000),
«What Drives Private Saving Across the World?», Review
of Economics and Statistics, May 2000, 82(2), pp. 165-181.
40. Lucas, R. E. (1988), «On the Mechanics of Economic
Development", Journal of monetary economics.
41. Margaret z. C. (2004), «Geographic Deregulation
of Banking and Economic Growth", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
Vol. 36, No. 5 (Oct., 2004), pp. 929-942.
42. Mauro, P. (1995), «Corruption and Growth",
Quarterly Journal of economics.
43. McKinnon, R.I (1973), «Money and capital in
Economic Development", Washington, D.C, Brookings institutions.
44.
Michael, W. K. and Giovanni, P. O. (2001), «Capital
Account Liberalization, Financial depth, and Economic Growth", Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston, Boston.
45. Murgatroyd. P, Dry. J, Power T. and Postgate W. (2007),
«Rwanda financial sector development program, First initiative»,
Kigali, Rwanda
46. National Bank of Rwanda (2004, 2008 and 2009),
«Annual report 2003, 2007 and 2008", Kigali, Rwanda
47. National Institute of Statistics of Rwanda (2008, 2007),
«Rwanda Development Indicators- 2006, 2007", Rwanda.
48. Rajan, R.C and Zingales, L. (1998),
«Financial Dependence and Growth", American Economic Review
88, pp. 559-586.
49. Raymond, F. and Love, I. (2004), «Financial
development and Growth in the Short and Long Run", World Bank, Policy
Research Paper 3319
50. Robinson, J. (1952), «The Generalization of the
General Theory , The Rate of Interest and Other Essays", London, Macmillan, pp.
69 -142
51. Sakutukwa, T. (2008), «The Financial Sector
Deepening, Sophistication and Growth Nexus", University of Zimbabwe,
Unpublished MA thesis.
52. Schumpeter, J.A. (1911), "The Theory of Economic
Development, An Inquiry into the Profits, Capital, Credit Interests and the
Business Cycles", Cambridge, MA: Harvard, University press.
53. Shaw, E. S. (1973), "Financial deepening in Economic
Development", New York, Oxford University Press.
54. Sims, C. A (1980), «Macro economics and
Reality", Econometrica
55. Singh, A. (1997), «Financial Liberalization, Stock
Market and Economic Development,» The Economics Journal, 107,
771-782
56. Sinha, D. and Macri, J. (2001), «Financial
Development and Economic Growth: The Case of eight Asian countries»,
Journal of Economic Literature, C32, E51, 010
57. Spears, A. (1991), «Financial Development and
Economic Growth-Causality tests", Atlantic Economic Journal.
58. Stiglitz, J. E. (I 994), «The Role of the State
in Financial Markets", In Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Bank
Conference on Development Economics 1993 (ed. M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic),
Washington, D.C: World Bank, pp. I9-52.
59.
Stiglitz, J.E and Andrew, W. (1981), «Credit Rationing in
Market with Imperfect Information», American Economic Review, 71 (3), pp.
393-410.
60. Teame, G. (2002), «Financial Development and
Economic Growth in Sub-Saharan African Countries: Evidence from Time Series
analysis», Morehead State University, Morehead, KY 40351, USA.
61. Thangavelu, S.M. (2004), «Financial Development
and Economic Growth in Australia: An Empirical analysis", Empirical
economics, vol 29, issue 2, pp. 247-260
62. Tufano, P. (2002), «Financial innovations",
The Handbook of the Economics of Finance, North Hollande.
63. UNDP (2004), «Human Development Report 2003",
New York
64. United Nations Population Division (2008), «World
Population Prospects", Revision,
www.un.org/esa/population/
65. United Nations Statistics Division,
http://unstats.un.org/unsd/demographic/
66. Verbeek, M. (2004), A guide to modern econometrics,
2nd ed, John Wiley & Sons, England.
67. Wooldridge, J. M, (1990), «Introductory
econometrics", a modern approach, 2nd ed,
68. World Bank, «World Development indicators
Database",
http://web.worldbank.org.
69. Yongfu, H. (2005), «What determines financial
development?", Discussion Paper No. 05/580, University of Bristol.
70. Zhang. J, Guanghua W. and Yu J. (2007),
«The Financial Deepening: Productivity Nexus in China:
1987-2001», World Institute for Economic development research, the United
Nations University, Research Paper No. 2007/08.
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
APPENDICES
Appendix A: Comparison of financial development i n EAC
Table A.1: Average ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP i n EAC
Period
|
Rwanda
|
Burundi
|
Uganda
|
Tanzania
|
Kenya
|
1970-1975
|
14.07
|
11.24
|
21.08
|
|
31.05
|
1976-1980
|
13.94
|
14.13
|
17.48
|
|
38.04
|
1981-1985
|
12.79
|
17.69
|
11.43
|
|
38.97
|
1986-1990
|
16.03
|
17.57
|
11.11
|
18.59
|
42.69
|
1991-1995
|
16.49
|
19.31
|
10.75
|
23.41
|
50.05
|
1995-2000
|
15.63
|
19.82
|
14.72
|
20.00
|
39.45
|
2001-2005
|
18.77
|
25.80
|
19.67
|
23.48
|
39.87
|
Overall average
|
15.35
|
17.75417
|
15.345
|
21.68
|
39.77
|
Rank
|
4
|
3
|
5
|
2
|
1
|
The regional average is 21.98
For Tanzania, data are available as from 1988.
Source: Author's calculation from data provided
by World Development Indicators database
Table A.2: Average ratio of claims o n private sector to
GDP i n EAC
Period
|
Rwanda
|
Burundi
|
Uganda
|
Tanzania
|
Kenya
|
1970=1975
|
3.39
|
5.82
|
8.98
|
|
19.11
|
1976=1980
|
5.00
|
7.46
|
8.93
|
|
25.66
|
1981=1985
|
6.45
|
10.65
|
4.65
|
|
30.16
|
1986=1990
|
8.19
|
11.21
|
3.24
|
9.85
|
30.82
|
1991=1995
|
7.08
|
16.98
|
4.06
|
10.19
|
32.32
|
1995=2000
|
8.60
|
19.28
|
5.72
|
4.05
|
26.97
|
2001=2005
|
11.41
|
25.73
|
6.62
|
7.52
|
25.83
|
Overall average
|
7.06
|
25.73
|
6.11
|
7.68
|
27.18
|
The regional average is 14.75
For Tanzania, data are available as from 1988.
Source: Author's calculation from data provided
by World Development Indicators database
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Table A.3: Average domestic credit to GDP ratio i n
EAC
Period
|
Rwanda
|
Burundi
|
Uganda
|
Tanzania
|
Kenya
|
1970-1975
|
12.39
|
9.45
|
13.32
|
|
23.85
|
1976-1980
|
5.27
|
12.09
|
25.36
|
|
34.98
|
1981-1985
|
7.39
|
23.96
|
19.06
|
|
47.01
|
1986-1990
|
14.15
|
24.61
|
25.10
|
28.21
|
49.64
|
1991-1995
|
17.51
|
20.89
|
12.69
|
28.38
|
50.91
|
1995-2000
|
12.36
|
27.52
|
8.01
|
13.07
|
40.38
|
2001-2005
|
11.54
|
36.62
|
11.81
|
10.11
|
39.51
|
Overall average
|
11.54
|
21.81
|
16.48
|
19.02
|
40.42
|
Source: Author's calculation from data provided
by World Development Indicators database
Appendix B: Granger causality
test
Pairwise Granger Causality Tests Date: 12/15/09 Time: 21:35
Sample: 1964 2005
Lags: 5
Null Hypothesis:
|
Obs
|
F-Statistic
|
Probability
|
DEPTH does not Granger Cause GRATE
|
36
|
55.5580
|
9.8E-13
|
GRATE does not Granger Cause DEPTH
|
|
0.02080
|
0.99980
|
DSOPHT does not Granger Cause GRATE
|
36
|
3.52734
|
0.01503
|
GRATE does not Granger Cause DSOPHT
|
|
4.06239
|
0.00777
|
DBANK does not Granger Cause GRATE
|
36
|
0.73037
|
0.60738
|
GRATE does not Granger Cause DBANK
|
|
0.06634
|
0.99662
|
PRIVATE does not Granger Cause GRATE
|
36
|
1.70944
|
0.16923
|
GRATE does not Granger Cause PRIVATE
|
|
1.40536
|
0.25647
|
DSOPHT does not Granger Cause DEPTH
|
36
|
1.93549
|
0.12400
|
DEPTH does not Granger Cause DSOPHT
|
|
4.77110
|
0.00338
|
DBANK does not Granger Cause DEPTH
|
36
|
0.10249
|
0.99071
|
DEPTH does not Granger Cause DBANK
|
|
2.18163
|
0.08847
|
PRIVATE does not Granger Cause DEPTH
|
37
|
0.71712
|
0.61635
|
DEPTH does not Granger Cause PRIVATE
|
|
1.30701
|
0.29164
|
DBANK does not Granger Cause DSOPHT
|
36
|
0.81696
|
0.54904
|
DSOPHT does not Granger Cause DBANK
|
|
0.55867
|
0.73048
|
PRIVATE does not Granger Cause DSOPHT
|
36
|
1.32527
|
0.28578
|
DSOPHT does not Granger Cause PRIVATE
|
|
1.09960
|
0.38541
|
PRIVATE does not Granger Cause DBANK
|
36
|
2.85052
|
0.03597
|
DBANK does not Granger Cause PRIVATE
|
|
0.43293
|
0.82127
|
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Appendix C: Vector Error Correction Estimates, model 4 i
n Eviews
Vector Error Correction Estimates
Date: 12/15/09 Time: 20:04
Sample (adjusted): 1969 2005
Included observations: 37 after adjustments Standard errors in (
) & t-statistics in [ ]
Cointegrating Eq:
|
CointEq1
|
|
|
|
|
GRATE(-1)
|
1.000000
|
|
|
|
|
DEPTH(-1)
|
0.332100
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.11144)
|
|
|
|
|
|
[ 2.98006]
|
|
|
|
|
SOPHT(-1)
|
-0.057857
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.05848)
|
|
|
|
|
|
[-0.98942]
|
|
|
|
|
BANK(-1)
|
0.298156
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.08532)
|
|
|
|
|
|
[ 3.49472]
|
|
|
|
|
PRIVATE(-1)
|
-0.114378
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.06522)
|
|
|
|
|
|
[-1.75373]
|
|
|
|
|
@TREND(64)
|
0.001995
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.00120)
|
|
|
|
|
|
[ 1.66116]
|
|
|
|
|
C
|
-0.109284
|
|
|
|
|
Error Correction:
|
D(GRATE)
|
D(DEPTH)
|
D(SOPHT)
|
D(BANK)
|
D(PRIVATE)
|
CointEq1
|
-2.032065
|
-1.163989
|
-0.720578
|
-0.251856
|
-0.157054
|
|
(0.22472)
|
(0.56523)
|
(0.28767)
|
(0.39386)
|
(0.22592)
|
|
[-9.04258]
|
[-2.05932]
|
[-2.50489]
|
[-0.63946]
|
[-0.69519]
|
D(GRATE(-1))
|
0.635997
|
0.512173
|
0.247474
|
-0.009307
|
0.047996
|
|
(0.18428)
|
(0.46352)
|
(0.23590)
|
(0.32299)
|
(0.18527)
|
|
[ 3.45116]
|
[ 1.10496]
|
[ 1.04904]
|
[-0.02882]
|
[ 0.25906]
|
D(GRATE(-2))
|
0.251038
|
0.263218
|
0.130006
|
0.132536
|
0.092150
|
|
(0.10913)
|
(0.27450)
|
(0.13970)
|
(0.19127)
|
(0.10971)
|
|
[ 2.30028]
|
[ 0.95890]
|
[ 0.93058]
|
[ 0.69292]
|
[ 0.83991]
|
D(GRATE(-3))
|
0.087797
|
-0.105592
|
-0.016569
|
-0.043783
|
-0.023816
|
|
(0.07554)
|
(0.19001)
|
(0.09670)
|
(0.13240)
|
(0.07594)
|
|
[ 1.16222]
|
[-0.55573]
|
[-0.17134]
|
[-0.33069]
|
[-0.31360]
|
D(DEPTH(-1))
|
0.695429
|
-0.758239
|
0.215837
|
0.068061
|
0.104795
|
|
(0.08377)
|
(0.21071)
|
(0.10724)
|
(0.14683)
|
(0.08422)
|
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
[ 8.30121] [-3.59845] [ 2.01265] [ 0.46355] [ 1.24430]
D(DEPTH(-2)) 0.866526 -0.790565 -0.013760 -0.157924 -0.021024
(0.09146) (0.23004) (0.11708) (0.16029) (0.09194)
[ 9.47464] [-3.43667] [-0.11753] [-0.98523] [-0.22866]
D(DEPTH(-3)) 0.963663 -0.491379 0.112484 0.041585 0.061428
(0.08089) (0.20346) (0.10355) (0.14177) (0.08132)
[ 11.9130] [-2.41509] [ 1.08628] [ 0.29332] [ 0.75537]
D(SOPHT(-1)) -0.090012 1.010779 0.171212 0.449488 -0.118463
(0.17793) (0.44754) (0.22777) (0.31185) (0.17888)
[-0.50588] [ 2.25852] [ 0.75168] [ 1.44136] [-0.66225]
D(SOPHT(-2)) 0.431769 0.540692 0.505270 0.034316 -0.012187
(0.23061) (0.58004) (0.29520) (0.40417) (0.23184)
[ 1.87230] [ 0.93217] [ 1.71159] [ 0.08490] [-0.05257]
D(SOPHT(-3)) 0.437132 1.215253 0.181885 -0.170377 -0.015982
(0.24017) (0.60408) (0.30744) (0.42093) (0.24145)
[ 1.82010] [ 2.01173] [ 0.59161] [-0.40476] [-0.06619]
D(BANK(-1)) 0.408020 -0.117947 0.304158 -0.517110 -0.034987
(0.12039) (0.30282) (0.15412) (0.21101) (0.12103)
[ 3.38905] [-0.38950] [ 1.97355] [-2.45067] [-0.28907]
D(BANK(-2)) 0.188578 -0.139547 0.219934 -0.160104 0.000816
(0.13695) (0.34446) (0.17531) (0.24002) (0.13768)
[ 1.37701] [-0.40512] [ 1.25456] [-0.66704] [ 0.00593]
D(BANK(-3)) 0.071952 0.000327 0.039480 -0.148662 0.020364
(0.11299) (0.28420) (0.14464) (0.19803) (0.11359)
[ 0.63680] [ 0.00115] [ 0.27296] [-0.75071] [ 0.17927]
D(PRIVATE(-1)) -0.165391 0.078972 0.292223 1.119834 0.627575
(0.22021) (0.55388) (0.28189) (0.38595) (0.22138)
[-0.75106] [ 0.14258] [ 1.03664] [ 2.90150] [ 2.83481]
D(PRIVATE(-2)) 0.118144 0.578400 -0.701639 -1.260416 -0.528714
(0.26649) (0.67028) (0.34113) (0.46706) (0.26790)
[ 0.44334] [ 0.86293] [-2.05680] [-2.69864] [-1.97352]
D(PRIVATE(-3)) -0.370708 -0.594595 0.504420 0.953775 0.488117
(0.23649) (0.59482) (0.30273) (0.41448) (0.23775)
[-1.56756] [-0.99962] [ 1.66624] [ 2.30115] [ 2.05311]
C -0.037309 -0.056214 -0.008053 0.001519 0.010289
(0.01270) (0.03194) (0.01625) (0.02225) (0.01277)
[-2.93824] [-1.76007] [-0.49541] [ 0.06827] [ 0.80600]
R-squared 0.973212 0.675205 0.675713 0.629321 0.553143
Adj. R-squared 0.951782 0.415368 0.416283 0.332778 0.195658
Sum sq. resids 0.075749 0.479224 0.124129 0.232683 0.076558
S.E. equation 0.061542 0.154794 0.078781 0.107862 0.061870
F-statistic 45.41337 2.598578 2.604607 2.122192 1.547317
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Log likelihood 62.03727
|
27.90961
|
52.90027
|
41.27567
|
61.84092
|
Akaike AIC -2.434447
|
-0.589708
|
-1.940555
|
-1.312199
|
-2.423834
|
Schwarz SC -1.694296
|
0.150443
|
-1.200404
|
-0.572047
|
-1.683682
|
Mean dependent -0.010551
|
0.003519
|
0.021542
|
0.013534
|
0.015225
|
S.D. dependent 0.280267
|
0.202448
|
0.103115
|
0.132048
|
0.068986
|
Determinant resid covariance (dof adj.)
|
7.67E-12
|
|
|
|
Determinant resid covariance
|
3.54E-13
|
|
|
|
Log likelihood
|
267.8841
|
|
|
|
Akaike information criterion
|
-9.561301
|
|
|
|
Schwarz criterion
|
-5.599313
|
|
|
|
Appendix D: Impulse responses Table D.1: Response of
GRATE
Period
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.110866
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
2
|
0.023867
|
0.036527
|
-0.022561
|
0.022034
|
-0.019033
|
3
|
0.045515
|
0.057392
|
-0.011222
|
0.017968
|
-0.021072
|
4
|
0.037837
|
0.032946
|
-0.027505
|
0.019478
|
-0.022002
|
5
|
-0.000736
|
-0.156447
|
-0.013251
|
0.041177
|
-0.030501
|
6
|
0.040981
|
0.057379
|
-0.081924
|
0.064538
|
-0.026016
|
7
|
0.060685
|
0.043036
|
0.021506
|
0.014210
|
-0.044306
|
8
|
0.017915
|
0.013092
|
-0.094851
|
0.028416
|
-0.005168
|
9
|
0.029084
|
-0.001842
|
-0.018589
|
0.008837
|
-0.018867
|
10
|
0.045891
|
0.041967
|
-0.048016
|
0.020167
|
-0.018944
|
Table D.2: Response of DEPTH
Period
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.042684
|
0.160654
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
2
|
0.002765
|
0.004773
|
0.058156
|
-0.023008
|
0.001036
|
3
|
-0.015034
|
-0.010982
|
-0.020773
|
0.022494
|
0.004580
|
4
|
0.014703
|
0.001705
|
0.066186
|
0.015017
|
-0.027150
|
5
|
0.007187
|
0.013749
|
0.006914
|
0.036248
|
-0.014533
|
6
|
-0.003185
|
0.001136
|
0.017871
|
0.025522
|
-0.010883
|
7
|
-0.007141
|
0.001467
|
-0.003656
|
0.019751
|
-0.005619
|
8
|
-0.000708
|
0.007714
|
0.000523
|
0.020156
|
-0.011697
|
9
|
-0.002032
|
0.007852
|
-0.004548
|
0.016009
|
-0.001729
|
10
|
0.000490
|
0.027798
|
-0.007655
|
0.014797
|
-0.000593
|
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Table D.3: Response of SOPHT
Period
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
0.038394
|
-0.000441
|
0.063624
|
0.000000
|
0.000000
|
2
|
0.009317
|
-0.007543
|
0.048052
|
0.022701
|
-0.000784
|
3
|
0.013298
|
-0.045349
|
0.076042
|
0.029846
|
-0.022814
|
4
|
0.002239
|
-0.067715
|
0.059652
|
0.047068
|
-0.026556
|
5
|
-0.009531
|
-0.111113
|
0.050461
|
0.064027
|
-0.022623
|
6
|
-0.005816
|
-0.065377
|
0.013228
|
0.065899
|
-0.015404
|
7
|
-0.005667
|
-0.073800
|
0.025564
|
0.049785
|
-0.022808
|
8
|
-0.013739
|
-0.062946
|
-0.013155
|
0.048529
|
-0.006798
|
9
|
-0.008875
|
-0.054465
|
0.001052
|
0.037321
|
-0.001589
|
10
|
-0.004777
|
-0.042031
|
-0.007326
|
0.033000
|
-0.000490
|
Table D.4: Response of BANK
Period
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
-0.009479
|
-0.029774
|
-0.017866
|
0.102732
|
0.000000
|
2
|
-0.020419
|
-0.030066
|
-0.017083
|
0.046759
|
0.049504
|
3
|
-0.020012
|
-0.046101
|
-0.015663
|
0.062062
|
-0.010128
|
4
|
-0.022073
|
-0.053973
|
-0.028484
|
0.056945
|
0.002892
|
5
|
-0.031028
|
-0.042932
|
-0.054515
|
0.067285
|
0.042668
|
6
|
-0.032095
|
-0.033648
|
-0.073330
|
0.054373
|
0.042879
|
7
|
-0.024130
|
-0.038732
|
-0.053985
|
0.041184
|
0.014162
|
8
|
-0.028729
|
-0.032004
|
-0.062213
|
0.048800
|
0.027874
|
9
|
-0.027158
|
-0.017147
|
-0.069020
|
0.049787
|
0.048387
|
10
|
-0.025162
|
-0.027646
|
-0.059990
|
0.040059
|
0.034574
|
Table E.5: Response of PRIVATE
Period
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1
|
-0.011483
|
-0.017272
|
-0.032845
|
-0.000627
|
0.043381
|
2
|
-0.028385
|
-0.018496
|
-0.066202
|
-0.007133
|
0.062621
|
3
|
-0.027309
|
-0.033425
|
-0.069358
|
-0.014376
|
0.045964
|
4
|
-0.032068
|
-0.035136
|
-0.087287
|
-0.007855
|
0.049569
|
5
|
-0.038349
|
-0.036091
|
-0.101852
|
-0.003997
|
0.067366
|
6
|
-0.036011
|
-0.020427
|
-0.115238
|
-0.009908
|
0.067096
|
7
|
-0.033852
|
-0.027347
|
-0.103637
|
-0.018525
|
0.054122
|
8
|
-0.034832
|
-0.016688
|
-0.113550
|
-0.015450
|
0.062935
|
9
|
-0.031838
|
-0.007433
|
-0.108540
|
-0.018831
|
0.070705
|
10
|
-0.030825
|
-0.011657
|
-0.106150
|
-0.023011
|
0.065037
|
Cholesky Ordering: GRATE DEPTH SOPHT BANK PRIVATE
Financial Development and Economic Growth in Rwanda
Appendix E: Data used i n regressio
Year
|
GRATE
|
DEPTH
|
SOPHT
|
BANK
|
PRIVATE
|
1964
|
NA
|
0.003567
|
1.129139
|
0.475836
|
0.113383
|
1965
|
0.048485
|
0.004227
|
1.130658
|
0.341787
|
0.099034
|
1966
|
-0.037486
|
0.010537
|
1.164228
|
0.345649
|
0.177340
|
1967
|
0.055563
|
0.009915
|
1.163735
|
0.351485
|
0.165488
|
1968
|
0.146935
|
0.008540
|
1.159847
|
0.294774
|
0.137405
|
1969
|
0.070565
|
0.009846
|
1.161644
|
0.339016
|
0.155382
|
1970
|
0.076776
|
0.014748
|
1.186143
|
0.488350
|
0.259087
|
1971
|
-0.019097
|
0.019318
|
1.181634
|
0.497815
|
0.268026
|
1972
|
0.005437
|
0.015964
|
1.179762
|
0.425915
|
0.189329
|
1973
|
-0.067799
|
0.026595
|
1.130154
|
0.428836
|
0.257070
|
1974
|
0.017362
|
0.040935
|
1.247668
|
0.546795
|
0.357663
|
1975
|
-0.000595
|
0.039905
|
1.236495
|
0.642054
|
0.364344
|
1976
|
-0.003619
|
0.041519
|
1.234960
|
0.587458
|
0.452704
|
1977
|
0.034499
|
0.062877
|
1.261730
|
0.734113
|
0.666864
|
1978
|
-0.005994
|
0.067189
|
1.247740
|
0.750870
|
0.702281
|
1979
|
0.052668
|
0.053429
|
1.251533
|
0.299719
|
0.696933
|
1980
|
-0.074406
|
0.066907
|
1.266090
|
0.799979
|
0.768805
|
1981
|
-0.011330
|
0.072512
|
1.357483
|
0.820133
|
0.778868
|
1982
|
0.001500
|
0.070229
|
1.411169
|
0.774293
|
0.646393
|
1983
|
0.021422
|
0.068853
|
1.467646
|
0.640206
|
0.548492
|
1984
|
-0.064912
|
0.076254
|
1.490819
|
0.765571
|
0.590796
|
1985
|
0.013082
|
0.089206
|
1.593986
|
0.807424
|
0.649958
|
1986
|
0.023334
|
0.092167
|
1.535018
|
0.788841
|
0.616279
|
1987
|
-0.034698
|
0.091950
|
1.649092
|
0.734884
|
0.537472
|
1988
|
-0.019368
|
0.105786
|
1.717816
|
0.794134
|
0.542378
|
1989
|
-0.019548
|
0.113606
|
1.880272
|
0.733037
|
0.539081
|
1990
|
-0.000318
|
0.956633
|
1.891606
|
0.579472
|
0.407243
|
1991
|
0.065505
|
0.085020
|
1.853128
|
0.501527
|
0.384436
|
1992
|
0.133531
|
0.094628
|
1.669966
|
0.461350
|
0.337314
|
1993
|
0.005033
|
0.074622
|
1.547183
|
0.423396
|
0.344361
|
1994
|
-1.001928
|
0.117063
|
1.290698
|
0.416386
|
0.334644
|
1995
|
0.263302
|
0.095467
|
1.550642
|
0.515350
|
0.446272
|
1996
|
0.092791
|
0.075440
|
1.507496
|
0.508075
|
0.434577
|
1997
|
0.046666
|
0.088340
|
1.585262
|
0.558837
|
0.503790
|
1998
|
-0.013474
|
0.095899
|
1.654591
|
0.592536
|
0.527153
|
1999
|
-0.029921
|
0.102427
|
1.668137
|
0.587264
|
0.523328
|
2000
|
-0.001148
|
0.108580
|
1.808461
|
0.648908
|
0.595793
|
2001
|
0.012502
|
0.110456
|
1.992687
|
0.662939
|
0.613780
|
2002
|
0.058323
|
0.111606
|
2.031944
|
0.702052
|
0.598948
|
2003
|
-0.008825
|
0.117874
|
2.005127
|
0.726781
|
0.624340
|
2004
|
0.028703
|
0.123611
|
2.146887
|
0.768688
|
0.652522
|
2005
|
-0.243463
|
0.138750
|
1.956892
|
0.795546
|
0.700732
|
|